Free Republic
Browse · Search
News/Activism
Topics · Post Article

Skip to comments.

THE CASE FOR FREE TRADE
Hoover Digest (1997 No. 4) ^ | 1997 | Milton Friedman and Rose Friedman

Posted on 08/05/2003 9:34:52 AM PDT by 1rudeboy


HOOVER INSTITUTION

HOOVER DIGEST
1997 No. 4

Milton Friedman and Rose Friedman

THE CASE FOR FREE TRADE

In international trade, Hoover fellow Charles Wolf Jr. argues in a previous article, deficits don't much matter. Here the Friedmans discuss what does: freedom. A ringing statement of logic and principle.

It is often said that bad economic policy reflects disagreement among the experts; that if all economists gave the same advice, economic policy would be good. Economists often do disagree, but that has not been true with respect to international trade. Ever since Adam Smith there has been virtual unanimity among economists, whatever their ideological position on other issues, that international free trade is in the best interests of trading countries and of the world. Yet tariffs have been the rule. The only major exceptions are nearly a century of free trade in Great Britain after the repeal of the Corn Laws in 1846, thirty years of free trade in Japan after the Meiji Restoration, and free trade in Hong Kong under British rule. The United States had tariffs throughout the nineteenth century, and they were raised still higher in the twentieth century, especially by the Smoot-Hawley tariff bill of 1930, which some scholars regard as partly responsible for the severity of the subsequent depression. Tariffs have since been reduced by repeated international agreements, but they remain high, probably higher than in the nineteenth century, though the vast changes in the kinds of items entering international trade make a precise comparison impossible.

Today, as always, there is much support for tariffs--euphemistically labeled "protection," a good label for a bad cause. Producers of steel and steelworkers' unions press for restrictions on steel imports from Japan. Producers of TV sets and their workers lobby for "voluntary agreements" to limit imports of TV sets or components from Japan, Taiwan, or Hong Kong. Producers of textiles, shoes, cattle, sugar--they and myriad others complain about "unfair" competition from abroad and demand that government do something to "protect" them. Of course, no group makes its claims on the basis of naked self-interest. Every group speaks of the "general interest," of the need to preserve jobs or to promote national security. The need to strengthen the dollar vis-à-vis the deutsche mark or the yen has more recently joined the traditional rationalizations for restrictions on imports.

One voice that is hardly ever raised is the consumer's. That voice is drowned out in the cacophony of the "interested sophistry of merchants and manufacturers" and their employees. The result is a serious distortion of the issue. For example, the supporters of tariffs treat it as self evident that the creation of jobs is a desirable end, in and of itself, regardless of what the persons employed do. That is clearly wrong. If all we want are jobs, we can create any number--for example, have people dig holes and then fill them up again or perform other useless tasks. Work is sometimes its own reward. Mostly, however, it is the price we pay to get the things we want. Our real objective is not just jobs but productive jobs--jobs that will mean more goods and services to consume.

Another fallacy seldom contradicted is that exports are good, imports bad. The truth is very different. We cannot eat, wear, or enjoy the goods we send abroad. We eat bananas from Central America, wear Italian shoes, drive German automobiles, and enjoy programs we see on our Japanese TV sets. Our gain from foreign trade is what we import. Exports are the price we pay to get imports. As Adam Smith saw so clearly, the citizens of a nation benefit from getting as large a volume of imports as possible in return for its exports or, equivalently, from exporting as little as possible to pay for its imports.

The misleading terminology we use reflects these erroneous ideas. "Protection" really means exploiting the consumer. A "favorable balance of trade" really means exporting more than we import, sending abroad goods of greater total value than the goods we get from abroad. In your private household, you would surely prefer to pay less for more rather than the other way around, yet that would be termed an "unfavorable balance of payments" in foreign trade.

The argument in favor of tariffs that has the greatest emotional appeal to the public at large is the alleged need to protect the high standard of living of American workers from the "unfair" competition of workers in Japan or Korea or Hong Kong who are willing to work for a much lower wage. What is wrong with this argument? Don't we want to protect the high standard of living of our people?

The fallacy in this argument is the loose use of the terms "high" wage and "low" wage. What do high and low wages mean? American workers are paid in dollars; Japanese workers are paid in yen. How do we compare wages in dollars with wages in yen? How many yen equal a dollar? What determines the exchange rate?

Consider an extreme case. Suppose that, to begin with, 360 yen equal a dollar. At this exchange rate, the actual rate of exchange for many years, suppose that the Japanese can produce and sell everything for fewer dollars than we can in the United States--TV sets, automobiles, steel, and even soybeans, wheat, milk, and ice cream. If we had free international trade, we would try to buy all our goods from Japan. This would seem to be the extreme horror story of the kind depicted by the defenders of tariffs--we would be flooded with Japanese goods and could sell them nothing.

Before throwing up your hands in horror, carry the analysis one step further. How would we pay the Japanese? We would offer them dollar bills. What would they do with the dollar bills? We have assumed that at 360 yen to the dollar everything is cheaper in Japan, so there is nothing in the U.S. market that they would want to buy. If the Japanese exporters were willing to burn or bury the dollar bills, that would be wonderful for us. We would get all kinds of goods for green pieces of paper that we can produce in great abundance and very cheaply. We would have the most marvelous export industry conceivable.

Of course, the Japanese would not in fact sell us useful goods in order to get useless pieces of paper to bury or burn. Like us, they want to get something real in return for their work. If all goods were cheaper in Japan than in the United States at 360 yen to the dollar, the exporters would try to get rid of their dollars, would try to sell them for 360 yen to the dollar in order to buy the cheaper Japanese goods. But who would be willing to buy the dollars? What is true for the Japanese exporter is true for everyone in Japan. No one will be willing to give 360 yen in exchange for one dollar if 360 yen will buy more of everything in Japan than one dollar will buy in the United States. The exporters, on discovering that no one will buy their dollars at 360 yen, will offer to take fewer yen for a dollar. The price of the dollar in terms of the yen will go down--to 300 yen for a dollar or 250 yen or 200 yen. Put the other way around, it will take more and more dollars to buy a given number of Japanese yen. Japanese goods are priced in yen, so their price in dollars will go up. Conversely, U.S. goods are priced in dollars, so the more dollars the Japanese get for a given number of yen, the cheaper U.S. goods become to the Japanese in terms of yen.

The price of the dollar in terms of yen would fall, until, on the average, the dollar value of goods that the Japanese buy from the United States roughly equaled the dollar value of goods that the United States buys from Japan. At that price everybody who wanted to buy yen for dollars would find someone who was willing to sell him yen for dollars.

The actual situation is, of course, more complicated than this hypothetical example. Many nations, and not merely the United States and Japan, are engaged in trade, and the trade often takes roundabout directions. The Japanese may spend some of the dollars they earn in Brazil, the Brazilians in turn may spend those dollars in Germany, the Germans in the United States, and so on in endless complexity. However, the principle is the same. People, in whatever country, want dollars primarily to buy useful items, not to hoard, and there can be no balance of payments problem so long as the price of the dollar in terms of the yen or the deutsche mark or the franc is determined in a free market by voluntary transactions.

Why then all the furor about the "weakness" of the dollar? Why the repeated foreign exchange crises? The proximate reason is because foreign exchange rates have not been determined in a free market. Government central banks have intervened on a grand scale in order to influence the price of their currencies. In the process they have lost vast sums of their citizens' money (for the United States, close to two billion dollars from 1973 to early 1979). Even more important, they have prevented this important set of prices from performing its proper function. They have not been able to prevent the basic underlying economic forces from ultimately having their effect on exchange rates but have been able to maintain artificial exchange rates for substantial intervals. The effect has been to prevent gradual adjustment to the underlying forces. Small disturbances have accumulated into large ones, and ultimately there has been a major foreign exchange "crisis."

We could say to the rest of the world: We cannot force you to be free. But we believe in freedom and we intend to practice it.

In all the voluminous literature of the past several centuries on free trade and protectionism, only three arguments have ever been advanced in favor of tariffs that even in principle may have some validity.

First is the national security argument--the argument that a thriving domestic steel industry, for example, is needed for defense. Although that argument is more often a rationalization for particular tariffs than a valid reason for them, it cannot be denied that on occasion it might justify the maintenance of otherwise uneconomical productive facilities. To go beyond this statement of possibility and establish in a specific case that a tariff or other trade restriction is justified in order to promote national security, it would be necessary to compare the cost of achieving the specific security objective in alternative ways and establish at least a prima facie case that a tariff is the least costly way. Such cost comparisons are seldom made in practice.

The second is the "infant industry" argument advanced, for example, by Alexander Hamilton in his Report on Manufactures. There is, it is said, a potential industry that, if once established and assisted during its growing pains, could compete on equal terms in the world market. A temporary tariff is said to be justified in order to shelter the potential industry in its infancy and enable it to grow to maturity, when it can stand on its own feet. Even if the industry could compete successfully once established, that does not of itself justify an initial tariff. It is worthwhile for consumers to subsidize the industry initially--which is what they in effect do by levying a tariff--only if they will subsequently get back at least that subsidy in some other way, through prices lower than the world price or through some other advantages of having the industry. But in that case is a subsidy needed? Will it then not pay the original entrants into the industry to suffer initial losses in the expectation of being able to recoup them later? After all, most firms experience losses in their early years, when they are getting established. That is true if they enter a new industry or if they enter an existing one. Perhaps there may be some special reason why the original entrants cannot recoup their initial losses even though it may be worthwhile for the community at large to make the initial investment. But surely the presumption is the other way.

The infant industry argument is a smoke screen. The so-called infants never grow up. Once imposed, tariffs are seldom eliminated. Moreover, the argument is seldom used on behalf of true unborn infants that might conceivably be born and survive if given temporary protection; they have no spokesmen. It is used to justify tariffs for rather aged infants that can mount political pressure.

The third argument for tariffs that cannot be dismissed out of hand is the "beggar-thy-neighbor" argument. A country that is a major producer of a product, or that can join with a small number of other producers that together control a major share of production, may be able to take advantage of its monopoly position by raising the price of the product (the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries cartel is the obvious example). Instead of raising the price directly, the country can do so indirectly by imposing an export tax on the product--an export tariff. The benefit to itself will be less than the cost to others, but from the national point of view, there can be a gain. Similarly, a country that is the primary purchaser of a product--in economic jargon, has monopsony power--may be able to benefit by driving a hard bargain with the sellers and imposing an unduly low price on them. One way to do so is to impose a tariff on the import of the product. The net return to the seller is the price less the tariff, which is why this can be equivalent to buying at a lower price. In effect, the tariff is paid by the foreigners (we can think of no actual example). In practice this nationalistic approach is highly likely to promote retaliation by other countries. In addition, as for the infant industry argument, the actual political pressures tend to produce tariff structures that do not in fact take advantage of any monopoly or monopsony positions.

A fourth argument, one that was made by Alexander Hamilton and continues to be repeated down to the present, is that free trade would be fine if all other countries practiced free trade but that, so long as they do not, the United States cannot afford to. This argument has no validity whatsoever, either in principle or in practice. Other countries that impose restrictions on international trade do hurt us. But they also hurt themselves. Aside from the three cases just considered, if we impose restrictions in turn, we simply add to the harm to ourselves and also harm them as well. Competition in masochism and sadism is hardly a prescription for sensible international economic policy! Far from leading to a reduction in restrictions by other countries, this kind of retaliatory action simply leads to further restrictions.

We are a great nation, the leader of the world. It ill behooves us to require Hong Kong and Taiwan to impose export quotas on textiles to "protect" our textile industry at the expense of U.S. consumers and of Chinese workers in Hong Kong and Taiwan. We speak glowingly of the virtues of free trade, while we use our political and economic power to induce Japan to restrict exports of steel and TV sets. We should move unilaterally to free trade, not instantaneously but over a period of, say, five years, at a pace announced in advance.

Few measures that we could take would do more to promote the cause of freedom at home and abroad than complete free trade. Instead of making grants to foreign governments in the name of economic aid--thereby promoting socialism--while at the same time imposing restrictions on the products they produce--thereby hindering free enterprise--we could assume a consistent and principled stance. We could say to the rest of the world: We believe in freedom and intend to practice it. We cannot force you to be free. But we can offer full cooperation on equal terms to all. Our market is open to you without tariffs or other restrictions. Sell here what you can and wish to. Buy whatever you can and wish to. In that way cooperation among individuals can be worldwide and free.


Adapted from "The Tyranny of Controls" in Free to Choose: A Personal Statement, by Milton Friedman and Rose Friedman, published by Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, © 1980. To order, call 800-543-1918. Available from the Hoover Press is The Essence of Friedman, edited by Kurt R. Leube. To order, call 800-935-2882.


Milton Friedman is a senior research fellow at the Hoover Institution. He was awarded the Nobel Prize in economic sciences in 1976. Rose Friedman studied economics as a graduate student at the University of Chicago and has collaborated with Milton Friedman on several books.



TOPICS: Business/Economy; Editorial; Foreign Affairs; Front Page News; Government; News/Current Events; Philosophy
KEYWORDS: deficit; export; freetrade; import; leftwingactivists; protectionism; tariff; trade
Navigation: use the links below to view more comments.
first previous 1-2021-4041-6061-80 ... 121-132 next last
To: narby
Anything they might say, pro or con about the issue of free trade is no better than toilet paper. They have zero credibility.

Marx and Engels were much better at forecasting the domestic upheaval than they were at constructing a "utopian" alternative.
But what the heck, if you don't want to believe them, maybe you'll listen to Adam Smith. He warns us of the same thing:

Excerpted and condensed from:

Adam Smith: The Wealth of Nations, Book 4, Chapter 2

Of Restraints upon the Importation from Foreign Countries
of such Goods as can be produced at Home

The case in which it may sometimes be a matter of deliberation, how far, or in what manner, it is proper to restore the free importation of foreign goods, after it has been for some time interrupted, is, when particular manufactures, by means of high duties or prohibitions upon all foreign goods which can come into competition with them, have been so far extended as to employ a great multitude of hands. Humanity may in this case require that the freedom of trade should be restored only by slow gradations, and with a good deal of reserve and circumspection. Were those high duties and prohibitions taken away all at once, cheaper foreign goods of the same kind might be poured so fast into the home market as to deprive all at once many thousands of our people of their ordinary employment and means of subsistence. The disorder which this would occasion might no doubt be very considerable....

There you go, narby. Or don't you think that Adam Smith has any credibility either?

41 posted on 08/05/2003 10:49:38 AM PDT by Willie Green (Go Pat Go!!!)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 35 | View Replies]

To: Willie Green
>>>
...Were those high duties and prohibitions taken away all at once, ....
<<<

Of course, the same could be said about adding them all at once.
42 posted on 08/05/2003 10:52:02 AM PDT by evilC
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 41 | View Replies]

To: 1rudeboy
So a $1T trade deficit is better than a $500B one? We'd be worse off with a $1T trade surplus than a $1T trade deficit? I'll have what you're smoking.

China has a 5:1 advantage over us in imports/exports. Do you think China is 5 times better than we are?

Read Unrestricted War by People's Liberation Army Colonels Qiao Liang and Wang Xiangsui. They'll tell you how we are at war. Whether we realize it or not, it's been declared on us. It's a preferred method because it's a lot less messy than the traditional bombs and body bag kind.


43 posted on 08/05/2003 10:54:01 AM PDT by GraniteStateConservative (Putting government in charge of morality is like putting pedophiles in charge of children.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 1 | View Replies]

To: american spirit
The free traitors on this thread are gonna hammer you....
44 posted on 08/05/2003 10:54:32 AM PDT by taxed2death (A few billion here, a few trillion there...we're all friends right?)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 13 | View Replies]

To: underbyte
Go back and read the article about what happens to the dollars in international trade.

The idea that somehow there is any kind of "trade imbalance" anywhere is just laughable, except to the extent that central banks monkey with stuff.

If we could get away with getting shoes from China by sending them green colored paper, GREAT! But they will want to get something of value for that green colored paper, and will spend it somewhere else. For that green colored paper to ever be redeemed, by definition, it MUST be returned to the United States by purchasing something from here.

The only other alternative is that our green colored paper continues to circulate worldwide and is never returned here for the purchase of US produced goods. In that case, GREAT! Our green colored paper becomes the currency of the world, in which case, we control the world by the actions of the Federal Reserve Bank.

45 posted on 08/05/2003 10:58:23 AM PDT by narby (Terminate Gray Davis)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 32 | View Replies]

To: taxed2death
The free traitors on this thread are gonna hammer you....

As an ex-military guy, I resent that line. Any arguments I have are from my desire for a prosperous country for myself, and my grandkids to live in.

46 posted on 08/05/2003 11:01:00 AM PDT by narby (Terminate Gray Davis)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 44 | View Replies]

To: narby
So, to make "fair trade" in the US, we would have to heavily subsidise crops grown in New York City so farmers there have a chance.

I'm sure NYC farmers (if any) are eligible for the same federal crop subsidies available to farmers in Oklahoma, Kansas or Idaho.
But it's not surprising that a marxist free trader like yourself would confuse "equal opportunity" with "equal outcome".
LOL! Say hi to Jesse Jackson for us!

47 posted on 08/05/2003 11:02:14 AM PDT by Willie Green (Go Pat Go!!!)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 30 | View Replies]

To: Willie Green
The case in which it may sometimes be a matter of deliberation, how far, or in what manner, it is proper to restore the free importation of foreign goods, after it has been for some time interrupted, is, when particular manufactures, by means of high duties or prohibitions upon all foreign goods which can come into competition with them, have been so far extended as to employ a great multitude of hands. Humanity may in this case require that the freedom of trade should be restored only by slow gradations, and with a good deal of reserve and circumspection. Were those high duties and prohibitions taken away all at once, cheaper foreign goods of the same kind might be poured so fast into the home market as to deprive all at once many thousands of our people of their ordinary employment and means of subsistence. The disorder which this would occasion might no doubt be very considerable....

Now I understand every point you've made. You didn't learn English comprehension in school. What part about "all at once" don't you understand?

To save you the time of re-reading your own post and comprehending it, Smith's point is that once you've established trade barriers, you can't remove them "all at once" without disruptions.

Smith doesn't say, but I'll opine that the trade barriers were a stupid idea in the first place, since they directed industry in places different from where it would have otherwise gone. Smith's very clear implication in your own post, is that these ill advised trade barriers must be removed gradually to avoid sudden disruptions. And I completly agree.

48 posted on 08/05/2003 11:09:12 AM PDT by narby (Terminate Gray Davis)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 41 | View Replies]

To: narby
So do we...
49 posted on 08/05/2003 11:10:40 AM PDT by N3WBI3
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 40 | View Replies]

To: evilC
Of course, the same could be said about adding them all at once.

I am personally opposed to excessively high, protectionist, targetted tariffs. As with any policy advocated by special interests, they distort the market for the benefit of some, and to the detriment of others.

Instead, my preference is for a relatively low, flat-rate "revenue tariff" to be levied on ALL imported goods (as envisioned by our Founding Fathers). Such a tariff benefits ALL Americans by favoring development of domestic industries in our own market, while providing revenue for the federal Treasury and enabling further reduction of other forms of domestic taxation.

50 posted on 08/05/2003 11:11:00 AM PDT by Willie Green (Go Pat Go!!!)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 42 | View Replies]

To: Willie Green
marxist free trader like yourself

Dude, you're really confused.

If your desire is "fair trade", then any farm subsidies would never be enough in NYC. Farming is impossible under those economic conditions, so "fair trade" does not exist.

To have fair trade between New York and Oklahoma, farm subsidies will need to be drasically increased in NY, and software tarrifs will need to be imposed to help OK software companies.

Get it?

51 posted on 08/05/2003 11:12:47 AM PDT by narby (Terminate Gray Davis)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 47 | View Replies]

To: Willie Green
marxist free trader

I'm sorry. I'm a little slow myself this morning.

I didn't catch the funny oxymoron you made till just now.

52 posted on 08/05/2003 11:20:19 AM PDT by narby (Terminate Gray Davis)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 50 | View Replies]

To: narby
Should governments see to it that our foreign policy isn't put into the hands of foreign powers who control large parts of our economy?

Should governments allow "free" trade with nations who have declared economic war on us?

Our government is supposed to establish justice, insure domestic tranquility, provide for the common defense, promote the general welfare, and secure the blessings of liberty to ourselves and our posterity. Making sure we aren't destroyed through unfair trade practices could fall under every one of those phrases.
53 posted on 08/05/2003 11:21:39 AM PDT by GraniteStateConservative (Putting government in charge of morality is like putting pedophiles in charge of children.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 39 | View Replies]

To: Willie Green
Will you cut the "marxist free-trader" stuff? How would you feel if someone called you a Nazi protectionist?
54 posted on 08/05/2003 11:21:57 AM PDT by 1rudeboy
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 47 | View Replies]

To: Willie Green
What is a "revenue tariff" and how would it work?
55 posted on 08/05/2003 11:22:49 AM PDT by evilC
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 50 | View Replies]

To: narby
"For that green colored paper to ever be redeemed, by definition, it MUST be returned to the United States by purchasing something from here."

Nonsense. They can buy heliocopters from the french, yellowcake from nigeria, and planes from airbus....

They can pay their engineers internally to develop ballistic missles, who then can buy computers from Taiwan or clothes from hong kong after all it is cheaper to buy from them than the US.
56 posted on 08/05/2003 11:23:00 AM PDT by underbyte (Arrogance will drop your IQ 50 points)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 45 | View Replies]

To: narby
but I'll opine that the trade barriers were a stupid idea in the first place, since they directed industry in places different from where it would have otherwise gone.

Yep. Marxist one-worlders rue the day that America achieved economic independence from Britain and Europe.

"The prohibiting duties we lay on all articles of foreign manufacture which prudence requires us to establish at home, with the patriotic determination of every good citizen to use no foreign article which can be made within ourselves without regard to difference of price, secures us against a relapse into foreign dependency."

--Thomas Jefferson to Jean Baptiste Say, 1815.

Hey narby, you wouldn't happen to be one of those marxist anti-industrial kooks like Algore and the Unibomber, would you? You sure are beginning to sound like one of 'em.
57 posted on 08/05/2003 11:23:26 AM PDT by Willie Green (Go Pat Go!!!)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 48 | View Replies]

To: Willie Green
You have the best quotes.
58 posted on 08/05/2003 11:26:20 AM PDT by GraniteStateConservative (Willie Green for President...)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 57 | View Replies]

To: underbyte
So we should refuse to pay for imports in US dollars because someone might buy something with the money. Riight.
59 posted on 08/05/2003 11:26:33 AM PDT by 1rudeboy
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 56 | View Replies]

To: Willie Green
Frederic Bastiat, a 19th-century French satirist, once observed that the sun offered unfair competition to candle makers. If windows could be boarded up during the day, he argued, more jobs could be created making candles.

Source: The Economist

60 posted on 08/05/2003 11:30:15 AM PDT by 1rudeboy
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 57 | View Replies]


Navigation: use the links below to view more comments.
first previous 1-2021-4041-6061-80 ... 121-132 next last

Disclaimer: Opinions posted on Free Republic are those of the individual posters and do not necessarily represent the opinion of Free Republic or its management. All materials posted herein are protected by copyright law and the exemption for fair use of copyrighted works.

Free Republic
Browse · Search
News/Activism
Topics · Post Article

FreeRepublic, LLC, PO BOX 9771, FRESNO, CA 93794
FreeRepublic.com is powered by software copyright 2000-2008 John Robinson