Free Republic
Browse · Search
Bloggers & Personal
Topics · Post Article

To: Dr. Brian Kopp
I am quite familiar with the subject - apparently you are completely ignorant of the reality on the ground, history, and have a rather minority view among those who study demographics.

Among those who study demographics there is a universal acknowledgment that human population in increasing, and will continue to increase.

Because you don't seem to follow math very well I will explain something to you. 3.5 billion people need a birth rate roughly TWICE what 7 billion people have, in order to add a billion people to their population in the same amount of time.

Because we now have 7 billion people, rather than 6, a declining birth rate will STILL add another billion people faster than 6 billion at a higher birth rate added another billion.

I don't remember, back when there were only 6 billion people on Earth rather than 7, MISSING them in an economic sense.

Similarly, if the illegal population of these United States were to be economically encouraged to go home, it would not be an economic blight upon the USA because of their ‘missing’ population.

How do you reconcile your out of the mainstream view with the economic blight of those nations with huge birth rates, and the economic blight we suffer because of illegal immigration?

Shouldn't all those extra people provide an economic boon? Why don't they?

103 posted on 01/24/2012 7:27:27 AM PST by allmendream (Tea Party did not send the GOP to D.C. to negotiate the terms of our surrender to socialism.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 102 | View Replies ]


To: allmendream


              IS POPULATION GROWTH A DRAG ON ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT?

                                 Julian L. Simon1

                  This is the economic history of humanity in a nutshell:
             From 2 million or 200,000 or 20,000 or 2,000 years ago until
             the 18th Century there was slow growth in population, almost
             no increase in health or decrease in mortality, slow growth
             in the availability of natural resources (but not increased
             scarcity), increase in wealth for a few, and mixed effects
             on the environment.  Since then there has been rapid growth
             in population due to spectacular decreases in the death
             rate, rapid growth in resources, widespread increases in
             wealth, and an unprecedently clean and beautiful living
             environment in many parts of the world along with a degraded
             environment in the poor and socialist parts of the world.

             That is, more people and more wealth has correlated
             with more (rather than less) resources and a cleaner
             environment - just the opposite of what Malthusian
             theory leads one to believe.


             For many years until recently, it was thought by

        "development economists" that population growth is a drag upon

        economic development in poor countries.  And even after a

        considerable shift in professional opinion in the 1980s,

        population growth is commonly believed to hinder development.

        This belief was the underlying assumption at the United Nations'

        World Population Conference in Cairo in 1994 just as it was at

        previous  World Population Conferences and as it probably will be

        again at the World Population Conference in 2004, irrespective of

        respectable scientific opinion.

             In accord with the earlier professional opinion, since the

        early 1960's official institutions such as the U.S. State Depart-

        ment's Agency for International Development (AID), the World

        Bank, and the United Nations Fund for Population Activities

        (UNFPA), have acted on the assumption that population growth is

        the key determinant of economic development.  This belief has

        misdirected attention away from the central factor in a country's

        economic development: its economic and political system.  This

        misplaced attention has resulted in unsound economic advice being

        given to developing nations.  It also has caused (or allowed) the

        misdiagnosis of such world development problems as supplies of

        natural resources, starving children, illiteracy, pollution, and

        slow growth.

             From the 1970s through the date of this publication, the

        U.S. government directly and indirectly has been spending

        hundreds of milions of dollars annually in foreign assistance for

        family planning and other programs aimed at slowing population

        growth in the poorer countries.  Not only could these funds have

        been put to other purposes, but in some cases, the population

        control programs funded by U.S. taxpayers have involved coercive

        policies designed to reduce birth rates in LDCs.

             One reason that population growth has been viewed as a

        villain is that poor countries tend to have a high birth rate.

        And it seems "common sense" that if fewer babies were born, there

        would be more of the supposedly fixed quantities of food and

        housing to go around.  Furthermore, in earlier decades most

        economists did not have another persuasive explanation of growth

        and wealth.  Population growth became the villain by default.

             The belief that population growth slows economic development

        is not a wrong but harmless idea.  Rather, it has been the basis

        for inhumane programs of coercion and the denial of personal

        liberty in one of the most valued choices a family can make --

        the number of children that it wishes to bear and raise.  Also,

        harm has been done to the U. S. as donor of foreign aid, over and

        beyond the funds themselves, by way of money laundered through

        international organizations that comes back to finance domestic

        population propaganda organizations, and so on.  This topic has

        been addressed in detail elsewhere (Simon, 1981, Chapters 21, 22)

             This paper makes two points.  First, there is persuasive

        explanation for why some countries grow faster than others, and

        the explanation has nothing to do with population growth.  This

        factor leaves little room for population growth to be the cause

        of slow growth.  Second, there is persuasive direct statistical

        evidence that population growth is not associated negatively with

        economic development in the short or intermediate run, and may

        well be a positive influence in the long run.  A corollary is

        that a more dense population does not hamper population growth.

             In the very short run, additional people are an added

        burden.  But under conditions of freedom, population growth poses

        less of a problem in the short run, and brings many more benefits

        in the long run, than under conditions of government control.


           THE ROLE OF THE SOCIO-ECONOMIC SYSTEM IN ECONOMIC PROGRESS

             If there is another convincing explanation for the bulk of

        differences among countries in economic growth, then the

        likelihood that population growth is an important drag on

        development is logically diminished.  The most powerful evidence

        explaining the rate of economic progress is found in the

        aggregate statistics which relate economic-political systems to

        their rates of economic growth.

             Raymond Gastil (annual) categorizes the systems.  He grades

        each nation on three measures of liberty:  political, civil, and

        economic.  Economic liberty comprises two sub-measures -- the

        extent of government intervention in markets, and the level of

        personal economic liberty.

             Gerald Scully (1988) related Gastil's data to economic

        results.  Allowing for other relevant factors, he finds a strong

        relationship between each of the three liberty variables and the

        rate of economic growth during 1960 to 1980 among 115 nations.

        And when he folds all three measures of liberty into a single

        variable, he finds that nations characterized as "politically

        open, individual rights, and free market" had an average growth

        rate per capita of 2.73 percent, whereas those characterized as

        "politically closed, state rights, and command [economy]" had an

        average growth rate of 0.91 percent.  This is a huge difference

        in performance.

             Gary Becker (1989) deepens confidence in Scully's result

        with a study along the same lines which finds that "political

        democracy" is positively related to economic growth.  And using a

        somewhat different methods, Keith Marsden arrived at much the

        same now-solid conclusion.

             The results in China's agricultural sector before and after

        the 1979-1981 period are an important illustration of the

        decisive effect of the political and economic structure upon

        economic development.  Under a system of collective production

        where there was little incentive for farmers to work hard and

        take risks, but great incentive for them to loaf on the job, food

        production stagnated in the years before 1979.  The combination

        of bad weather and The Great Leap Forward during the years 1959

        to 1961 caused production to fall so drastically that 30 million

        people died of starvation.  This was certainly the worst food-

        production performance of any country in modern times, and

        perhaps the worst ever.

             Then the Chinese government undertook the largest and

        fastest social movement of all time.  Within a period of three

        years, the 700 million people in the agricultural sector shifted

        from collective enterprise to individual enterprise, and

        agriculture became the largest "private" sector in the world, by

        far.  And since then Chinese agricultural production has

        skyrocketed.  Per capita food production showed almost no

        increase from 1950 to 1978.  But starting with the reform in

        1979, per capita production almost doubled by 1985, a truly

        incredible increase, with continued growth since then and no

        limit in  sight.  The visitor to China is confronted with

        bounteous appetizing food on every streetcorner, it seems, in the

        sharpest contrast to the situation in the former Soviet Union.

             One may wonder whether the Chinese agricultural turnaround

        was "just" an isolated event, and could have other causes than

        the shift in social system.  We may therefore consult a wider

        range of experience, though using prose accounts rather than

        statistical analysis.  Sven Rydenfelt analyzed the experience of

        fifteen socialist countries on four continents and finds a

        pervasive pattern of economic failure.  However, each of these

        cases also can be "explained" on the basis of its individual

        culture rather than its socialist system.

             Most vivid is the eyeball evidence.  One need only travel by

        bus across the Karelian peninsula which was wholly within Finland

        until World War II.  The part that is still within Finland has

        incomparably better roads and more modern shops and facilities

        than the part that is now within the Soviet Union.  Or drive from

        West Berlin to East Berlin.  Or take the train from the mainland

        portion of Hong Kong across the border to China.  The differences

        in favor of a free-enterprise private-property society are

        literally unmistakable for all who are not entirely masked by

        ideological blinders.

             Evidence that is both dramatic and powerful statistically

        arises from the unique experiment that the world's political

        system created following World War II.  Three nations - Germany,

        Korea, and China - were split into socialist and non-socialist

        parts, producing three pairs of countries whose members began

        with the same culture and language and history.  The members of

        the pairs also had much the same standard of living when they

        split apart, and the same birth rates.  Their subsequent

        histories enable us to determine the effect of economic system,

        because it is the only relevant variable that differs between the

        elements of each pair.  These comparisons constitute a useful

        combination of scientific rigor with ease of communication and

        understanding.  (Similar comparisons can be made with such

        neighboring countries, one socialist and one capitalist, such as

        Austria with Czechoslovakia.)

             Other than the case of Korea, which will provide a

        continuing laboratory example, the results are now in and are

        known to all.  (For a full display of the data, please see the

        predecessor to this essay, Simon, 1990).

             Standard measures of development that show the huge

        differences in results with different socio-economic systems

        include:

        Output Per Person

             Whether per person is measured by either the exchange-rate

        method or the purchasing-power-parity method, the result of the

        comparison is the same.  The pairs began with roughly-equal

        incomes after World War II.  In each case, by the 1990s the

        communist country had a much lower income.  Taiwan's income is

        three or four times as high as China's, S. Korea's about twice as

        N. Korea's, and W. Germany's was vastly higher than E. Germany's.

             Differences in product quality are not reflected in the

        standard statisticaly comparisons, but are important.  In East

        Germany the four-cylinder primitive Trabant was almost the only

        car one can buy.  A person had to work 3,807 hours to earn enough

        to purchase a Trabant, whereas in West Germany 607 hours work

        paid for a much better car.  And people had to wait in line for

        ten years to get a car in East Germany.

             A refrigerator required 293 hours of work in East Germany,

        but only 40 hours in West Germany; a suit required 67 hours of

        work, versus 13 hours in West Germany.

             Only 36 percent of housing facilities in East Germany

        hadcentral heating, 60 percent an indoor toilet, and 68 percent a

        bath or shower.  In West Germany the corresponding percentages

        were 70 percent, 95 percent, and 92 percent.

        Life and Health

             Goods only have value if one is alive to enjoy them.

        Concerning the number of years that a newly-born person could

        expect to live, the free-enterprise countries did better in each

        pair, though each pair started out with much the same life-

        expectancy after World War II.  The same is true of the results

        for infant mortality.  These results are particularly interesting

        because public health had been one of the more-successful

        activities of socialized countries.  And indeed, for a while the

        differences between the members of pairs were small. But

        throughout Eastern Europe, life expectancy actually fell in the

        last decades of the socialist experiment, and infant mortality

        has increased. This reversal is not yet well-understood, but it

        certainly stemmed from a congeries of characteristics of a

        publicly-run health system, and from the general poverty of

        socialized economies.

        Proportion of the Labor Force in Agriculutre

             The best long-run indicator of the extent of development of

        a society is the proportion of the labor force that is employed

        in agriculture.  The fewer the people that are needed to feed the

        population, the larger the number of people that can be employed

        in providing other goods.  The countries with freer markets --

        including freer labor markets and freer agriculture -- needed

        fewer people to feed the rest.

        Economic Infra-structure

             The number of telephones is a good measure of the

        development of a country's infra-structure, and more particularly

        its crucial communications infra-structure.  The communist

        countries lagged behind the development of the market-oriented

        countries.

             These data for the paired-country experiments in political

        and economic systems provide evidence that is well-grounded

        scientifically as well as dramatic and easily-understood.  They

        prove that the socio-economic system is the main determinant of

        economic growth.  There is little other variation in

        developmental rates that might be explained by population

        growth.


           POPULATION GROWTH AND DENSITY AS INFLUENCES ON DEVELOPMENT

             The paired-country data corroborate a larger body of other

        scientific studies which show that population growth and density

        do not hamper development.  The first line in Table 1 shows that

        in each split-country case the centrally-planned communist

        country began with less population "pressure," as measured by

        density per square kilometer, compared to the paired market-

        directed non-communist country.  And the communist and non-

        communist countries in each pair also started with much the same

        birth rates and population growth rates.  There is certainly no

        evidence here which suggests that population growth or density

        influences the rate of economic development.    Contrary to the

        idea that population growth necessarily inhibits economic growth,

        the free market countries, each with faster expansion in

        population, experienced more rapid development -- on a per capita

        basis -- than their neighboring socialist nations.  If anything,

        the data show that more people have a positive effect on

        development.

             The most powerful evidence on the relationship between the

        rate of population growth and the rate of economic growth are the

        global correlations.  There now exist perhaps a score of

        competent statistical studies, beginning in 1967 with an analysis

        by Simon Kuznets covering the few countries for which data are

        available over the past century, and also analyses by Kuznets

        (1967) and Richard Easterlin (1967) of the data covering many

        countries since World War II.  The basic method is to gather data

        on each country's rate of population growth and its rate of

        economic growth, and then to examine whether -- looking at all

        the data in the sample together -- the countries with high

        population growth rates have economic growth rates lower than

        average, and countries with low population growth rates have

        economic growth rates higher than average.  Various writers have

        used a variety of samples of countries, and they have employed an

        impressive battery of ingenious statistical techniques to allow

        for other factors that might also be affecting the outcome.

             The clear-cut consensus of this body of research is that

        faster population growth is not associated with slower economic

        growth.  Of course one can adduce cases of countries that

        seemingly are exceptions to the pattern.  It is the genius of

        statistical inference, however, to enable us to draw valid

        generalizations from samples that contain such wide variations in

        behavior.  The exceptions can be useful in alerting us to

        possible avenues for further analysis, but as long as they are

        only exceptions, they do not prove that the generalization is not

        meaningful or useful.

             It has been suggested (e.g. by Roger Conner, 1984) that the

        studies showing the absence of a relationship between the

        population rate and the economic growth rate also demonstrate

        that additional people do not imply a higher standard of living

        in the long run. That is, because these studies do not show a

        positive correlation, one is said to make claims beyond the

        evidence if one says that over the very long sweep of human

        history a larger population in the world (or perhaps, in what is

        the developed part of the world at any moment) has meant faster

        rates of increase of technology and the standard of living.

             It is indeed the case that the existing body of empirical

        studies does not prove that fast population growth in the more-

        developed world as a whole increases per person income.  But this

        is not inconsistent with the proposition that more people do

        raise the standard of living in the long run.  Recall that the

        studies mentioned above do not refer to the very long run, but

        rather usually cover only a quarter of a century, or a century at

        most.  The main negative effects of population growth occur

        during perhaps the first quarter or half of a century so that, if

        these effects are important, the empirical studies referred to

        should reveal them.  These shorter-run effects upon the standard

        of living include the public costs of raising children -- schools

        and hospitals are the main examples -- and the costs of providing

        additional production capital for the additional persons in the

        work force.  The absence of an observed negative effect upon

        economic growth in the statistical measures therefore is enough

        to imply that in the very long run more people have a positive

        net effect.  This is because the most important positive effects

        of additional people -- improvement of productivity through both

        the contribution of new ideas, and also the learning-by-doing

        consequent upon increased production volume -- happen in the long

        run, and are cumulative.  To put it differently, the statistical

        measurements of the relationship of population growth to economic

        growth are biased in favor of showing the shorter-run effects,

        which tend to be negative, and not showing the longer-run

        effects, which tend to be positive.  If such negative effects do

        not appear, one may assume that an unbiased measure of the total

        effect would reveal a positive effect of population growth upon

        economic growth.

             There is still another reason why the studies mentioned

        above do not imply an absence of positive effect in the long run:

        They focus on the process of population growth.  If we look

        instead at the attained level of population -- that is, the

        population density as measured by the number of persons per

        square mile, say -- we see a somewhat different result.  Studies

        of MDC's are lacking.  But Everett Hagen (l975) and Charles

        Kindleberger (l965) show visually, and Simon and Roy Gobin (l979)

        show in multivariate regressions, that in LDC's higher population

        density is associated with higher rates of economic growth; this

        effect may be strongest at low densities, but there is no

        evidence that the effect reverses at high densities.  Again, the

        statistical evidence directly contradicts the common-sense

        conventional wisdom.  That is, if you make a chart with

        population density on the horizontal axis and either the income

        level or the rate of change of income on the vertical axis, you

        will see that higher density is associated with better rather

        than poorer economic results.

             The data showing a positive effect of density upon economic

        growth constitute indirect proof of a positive long-run effect of

        population growth upon economic growth, because density changes

        occur very slowly, and therefore the data pick up the very-long-

        run effects as well as the short run effects.3

             Hong Kong is a vivid example of this phenomenon.  In the

        1940's and 1950's, it seemed impossible for Hong Kong to surmount

        its problems -- huge masses of impoverished people without jobs,

        total lack of exploitable natural resources, more refugees

        pouring across the border each day.  Today, Hong Kong enjoys high

        living standards, low unemployment, an astounding collection of

        modern high-rise apartments and office buildings, and one of the

        world's most modern transportation systems.  Hong Kong starkly

        demonstrates that a very dense concentration of human beings does

        not prevent comfortable existence and exciting economic

        expansion, as long as the economic system gives individuals the

        freedom to exercise their talents and to take advantage of

        opportunities.  And the experience of Singapore demonstrates that

        Hong Kong is not unique.

             Check for yourself: Fly over Hong Kong -- just a few decades

        ago a place seemingly without prospects because of insoluble

        resource problems -- and you will marvel at the skyline of

        buildings.  Take a ride on its excellent smooth-flowing highways

        for an hour or two, and you will realize that a very dense

        concentration of human beings does not prevent comfortable

        existence and a rapid rate of economic growth.2

             At this point the question frequently arises:  If more

        people cause there to be more ideas and knowledge, and hence

        higher productivity and income, why are not India and China the

        richest nations in the world?  Let us put aside the matter that

        size in terms of population within national boundaries was not

        very meaningful in earlier centuries when national integration

        was much looser than it is now.  There remains the question,

        however, why so many human beings in those countries produced so

        little change in the last few hundred years.  Yes, low education

        of most people in China and India prevents them from producing

        knowledge and change (though we should note the very large, in

        absolute terms, contemporary scientific establishments in those

        two countries.)  But though education may account for much of the

        present situation, it does not account nearly as well for the

        differences between the West and the East over the five centuries

        or so up to, say, l850.

             William McNeill (l963), Eric Jones (1981) and others have

        suggested that over several centuries the relative instability of

        social and economic life in Europe, compared to China and India,

        helps account for the emergence of modern growth in the West

        rather than in the East.  Instability implies economic

        disequilibria, which (as Theodore Schultz [1975] reminds us)

        imply exploitable opportunities which then lead to augmented

        effort.  (Such disequilibria also cause the production of new

        knowledge, it would seem.)

              The hypothesis that the combination of a person's wealth

        and opportunities affect the person's exertion of effort may go

        far in explaining the phenomenon at hand.  Ceteris paribus, the

        less wealth a person has, the greater the person's drive to take

        advantage of economic opportunities.  The village millions in

        India and China certainly have had plenty of poverty to stimulate

        them.  But they have lacked opportunities because of the static

        and immobile nature of their village life.  In contrast,

        villagers in Western Europe apparently had more mobility, less

        stability, and more exposure to cross-currents of all kinds.

             Just why Europe should have been so much more open than

        India and China is a question that historians answer with

        conjectures about religion, smallness of countries with

        consequent competition and instability, and a variety of other

        special conditions.  This matter need not be pursued here.  But

        we should at least mention Lal's 1988 book on India's economic

        development over thousands of years, which suggests that it was

        only the rapid population growth starting around 1921 which

        cracked the "cake of custom" and the Hindu caste system, and

        caused the mobility which allowed India to begin modern

        development.

             Most (if not all) historians of the period (e.g. Nef, 1958/

        1963; Gimpel, 1976) agree that the period of rapid population

        growth from before AD 1000 to the beginning of the middle of the

        1300s was a period of extraordinary intellectual fecundity.  It

        was also a period of great dynamism generally, as seen in the

        extraordinary cathedral building boom.  But during the period of

        depopulation due to the plague (starting with the Black Death

        cataclysm) and perhaps to climatic changes from the middle 1300s

        (though the change apparently began earlier at the time of major

        famines around 1315-17, and perhaps even earlier, when there also

        was a slowing or cessation of population growth due to other

        factors) until perhaps the 1500s, historians agree that

        intellectual and social vitality waned.

             Henri Pirenne's magisterial analysis (1925/1969) of this

        period depends heavily upon population growth and size.  Larger

        absolute numbers were the basis for increased trade and

        consequent growth in cities, which in turn strongly influenced

        the creation of a more articulated exchange economy in place of

        the subsistence economy of the manor.  And according to Pirenne,

        growth in population also loosened the bonds of the serf in the

        city and thereby contributed to an increase in human liberty

        (though the causes of the end of serfdom are a subject of much

        controversy).

             A corollary, of course, is that once the people in the East

        lose the shackles of static village life and get some education,

        their poverty (absolute and relative) will drive them to an

        extraordinary explosion of creative effort.  The happenings in

        Taiwan and Korea in recent decades suggest that this is already

        beginning to occur.

             This explanation would seem more systematic, and more

        consistent with the large body of economic thought, than are

        explanations in terms of Confucianism or of particular cultures,

        just as the Protestant-ethic explanation for the rise of the West

        (discussion of which goes back at least to David Hume) now seems

        unpersuasive in the face of religious counter-examples (e.g. the

        Catholic Ibo in Nigeria) and shifts in behavior of Protestant

        nations.

             Though the statistical studies together with the historical

        analogies would seem to constitute persuasive evidence of the

        positive long-run effect of additional people, experience shows

        that it is not convincing.  Perhaps a few thought experiments in

        the form of hypothetical comparisons will add conviction.

        Therefore, please ask yourself:  i) Would the world be in better

        or worse shape today if all the people who have ever lived in the

        area now called the Netherlands (or India, or China, or Portugal,

        or wherever) had never lived at all?  ii) If you were colonizing

        another planet such as the moon or Saturn, would you prefer that

        ten, or a hundred, or a thousand, or a million, or ten million

        persons were also colonizing along with you?  Under which

        condition would exploration and mapping of the resources of the

        moon take place more rapidly?  Under which condition would the

        moon be more rapidly rendered habitable so that one could travel

        safely and find accommodations and a fast-food outlet?  iii) If

        you were Robinson Crusoe, would you have preferred that the

        island were not devoid of other humans, but rather contained some

        or many others?  Under which conditions do you think that you

        would be in less fear of your life, and feel less need to erect

        fortifications and stand watch at night?  Under which conditions

        would there be a greater pool of useful skills, and of the

        manpower to build a ship and leave the island?  Would the

        "congestion" of more people outweigh the isolation of none?  iv)

        Were the Pilgrims better or worse off for the the presence of

        Native Americans in the area when they arrived?


                                   CONCLUSION

             For 25 years our institutions have mis-analyzed such world

        development problems as starving children, illiteracy, pollution,

        supplies of natural resources and slow growth.  The World Bank,

        the State Department's Aid to International Development (AID),

        The United Nations Fund for Population Activities (UNFPA) and the

        environmental organizations have asserted that the cause is

        population growth -- the population "explosion" or "bomb" or

        "plague."  This error has cost dearly.  It has directed our

        attention away from the factor that we now know is central in a

        country's economic development, its economic and political

        system.  It suggests that attention be paid to population growth

        rather than to fighting tyranny and working for economic freedom.

        This error also has led to Westerners condoning and abetting

        inhumane programs of coercion of couples to prevent them having

        children in China and elsewhere.  Perhaps the events in Eastern

        Europe in 1989 and 1990 will open minds to the irrelevance of

        population growth for intermediate-run economic development, and

        to the all-importance of the social and economic system.



        page 1/article0 catonew/July 3, 1995

                                   REFERENCES


             Bauer, P.T., Reality and Rhetoric, (Studies in the Economics

        of Development) (Cambridge:  Harvard University Press, 1984).

             Becker, Gary, "An Environment for Economic Growth", The Wall

        Street Journal, Jan. 19, 1989, p. A8

        Easterlin

             Conner, Roger, "How Immigrants Affect Americans' Living

        Standard," A Debate Between Julian Simon and Roger Conner, The

        Heritage Foundation, May 30, 1984.

             Easterlin, Richard A. 1967. Effects of population growth in

        the economic development of of developing countries.  The Annals

        of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 369:98-

        108.

             Gastil, Raymond D., Freedom in the World (Westport, Conn:

        Greenwood, yearly ), cited by Scully

        Hagen

             Hagen, Everett E. 1975. The economics of development. Home-

        wood, Ill.: Irwin.

             Jones, Eric L., The European Miracle (New York: Cambridge

        UP, 1981).

             Kasun, Jacqueline R., The War Against Population:  The

        Economics and Ideology of World Population Control (Ottawa, Ill:

        Jameson Books, 1986).

             Kelley, Allen,  and Robert Schmidt, "Population and Income

        Change", World Bank Discussion Paper 249, 1994.

             Kindleberger, Charles P.  Economic Development.  2nd Edition

        (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1965)

             Krueger, Anne O., "Aid in the Development Process," The

        World Bank Research Observer, l, January, 1986.

                  Kuznets, Simon, "Population and economic growth".

        Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society 11:,  1967.

        170-93.

             Lal, Deepak, The Hindue Equilibrium: Cultural Stability and

        Economic Stagnation:  India 1500 BC-1980 AD (New York:  Oxford:

        Clarendon Press, 1988).

             Keith Marsden, "Why Asia Boomed and Africa Busted," WSJ,

        June 3, 1985, op ed page.

             McNeill, W. H., The Rise of the West - A History of the

        Human Community (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press,

        1963).

             Nef, John V., Western Civilization Since the Renaissance

        (New York: Harper and Row, 1950/1963).

             Pirenne, Henri, Medieval Cities (Princeton: Princeton

        University Press, 1925/1969).

             Repetto, Robert, "Why Doesn't Julian Simon Believe His Own

        Research?", Letter to the Editor, The Washington Post, Nov. 2,

        1985, p. A 21.

             Schultz, Theodore W., "The Value of the Ability to Deal with

        Disequilibria'," in Journal of Economic Literature, 1975,

        pp. 827-46.

             Schultz, Theodore W., Investing in People  (Chicago:  U. of

        Chicago Press, 1981)

             Scully, Gerald W., "Liberty and Economic Progress", Journal

        of Economic Growth, Vol 3, Nov., 1988, pp. 3-10;

             Scully, Gerald W., "The Institutional Framework and Economic

        Development", Journal of Political Economy, Vol 96, June, 1988,

        pp. 652-662.]

             Rydenfelt, Sven,  A Pattern for Failure (New York:  Harcourt

        Brace Jovanovich, 1983)

             Simon, Julian L., "The Concept of Causality in Economics,"

        Kyklos, Vol. 23, Fasc. 2, 1970, pp. 226-254.

             Simon, Julian L.,  The Ultimate Resource (Princeton; PUP,

        1981, second edition forthcoming)

             Simon, Julian L., Population and Development Review, June,

        1989

             Simon, Julian L., , and Roy Gobin.  "The relationship

        between population and economic growth in LDC's.  In Julian L.

        Simon and Julie deVanzo, eds., Research in Population Economics.

        Vol. 2.  (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press, 1979)



        page 2/article0 catonew/July 3, 1995

                                   FOOTNOTES



             1In this paper I draw freely upon a variety of Simon's other

        writings that have touched upon the subjects at hand, especially

        "Why Do We Still Think Babies Create Poverty", Washington Post,

        October 12, 1985; and "The War on People", Challenge, March-

        April, 1985, pp. 50-53.  I appreciate comments by Jim Dorn, David

        Boaz and Theodore W. Schultz.  Stephen Moore helped prepare the

        tabular material.

             2Hong Kong is a special thrill for me because I first saw it

        in 1955 when I went ashore from a U.S. Navy destroyer.  At the

        time I felt great pity for the thousands of people who slept

        every night on the sidewalks or on small boats.  It then seemed

        clear to me, as it must have to almost every observer, that it

        would be impossible for Hong Kong to surmount its problems --

        huge masses of impoverished people without jobs, total lack of

        exploitable natural resources, more refugees pouring across the

        border each day.  And it is this sort of picture that has

        convinced many persons that a place is "overpopulated" and should

        cut its birth rate (e.g. Ehrlich at the beginning of The

        Population Bomb).  But upon returning in 1983, I saw bustling

        crowds of healthy, vital people full of hope and energy.  No

        cause for pity now.

              3It may at first seem preposterous that greater population

        density might lead to better economic results.  This is the

        equivalent of saying that if all Americans moved east of the

        Mississippi, we might not be the poorer for it.  Upon reflection,

        this proposition is not as unlikely as it sounds.  The main loss

        involved in such a move would be huge amounts of farmland, and

        though the United States is a massive producer and exporter of

        farm goods, agriculture is not crucial to the economy.  Less than

        3% of U.S. income comes from agriculture, and less than 3% of the

        U. S. working population is engaged in that industry.  The

        capitalized value of all U.S. farm land is just a bit more than a

        tenth of just one year's national income, so even if the U.S.

        were to lose all of it, the loss would equal only about one

        year's expenditures upon liquor, cigarettes, and the like.  On

        the other hand, such a change would bring about major benefits in

        shortening transportation and communication distances, a factor

        which has been important in Japan's ability to closely coordinate

        its industrial operations in such a fashion as to reduce costs of

        inventory and transportation.  Additionally, greater population

        concentration forces social changes in the direction of a greater

        degree of organization, changes which may be costly in the short

        run but in the long run increase a society's ability to reach its

        economic and social objectives.  If we were still living at the

        population density of, say, ten thousand years ago, we would have

        none of the vital complex social and economic apparatuses that

        are the backbone of our society.




        page 3/article0 catonew/July 3, 1995


        Wall Street Journal, Sept 4, 1987, p. 1, re the two Germanies

        On mark exchange rate:  Wash Post, Nov 15, 89 p.  A26




        page 4/article0 catonew/July 3, 1995



104 posted on 01/24/2012 7:32:54 AM PST by Brian Kopp DPM
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 103 | View Replies ]

To: allmendream
How do you reconcile your out of the mainstream view

Global warming was a mainstream view till not too long ago too.

105 posted on 01/24/2012 7:35:06 AM PST by Brian Kopp DPM
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 103 | View Replies ]

Free Republic
Browse · Search
Bloggers & Personal
Topics · Post Article


FreeRepublic, LLC, PO BOX 9771, FRESNO, CA 93794
FreeRepublic.com is powered by software copyright 2000-2008 John Robinson