Free Republic
Browse · Search
Bloggers & Personal
Topics · Post Article

Skip to comments.

The greatest threat facing mankind is...
Faith, Reason and Health Blog ^ | 01/22/12 | Various

Posted on 01/22/2012 4:54:42 PM PST by Brian Kopp DPM

click here to read article


Navigation: use the links below to view more comments.
first previous 1-20 ... 81-100101-120121-140 ... 161-171 next last
To: Dr. Brian Kopp
The “kool aid” that had us going from 6 billion to 7 billion faster than we went from 5 billion to 6? The “kool aid” that has us hitting 8 billion in an even shorter interval? The “kool aid” that has us possibly hitting up to 9 billion before a catastrophic collapse -as you proposed?

Sorry charlie, it isn't “kool aid”, it is reality.

But as I said, your religious bias on this subject is apparently insurmountable by evidence.

The evidence of 7 BILLION PEOPLE rapidly climbing to 8 and even 9 BILLION PEOPLE.

Oh, but it is UNDER population that is a problem - in Bizarro world!

101 posted on 01/24/2012 7:03:30 AM PST by allmendream (Tea Party did not send the GOP to D.C. to negotiate the terms of our surrender to socialism.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 100 | View Replies]

To: allmendream

As I said earlier, you obviously haven’t read the original post or the subsequent articles I posted on this thread.

You have no understanding of demographics and the interplay between life expectancy and fertility rates.

Read up on demographics and economics and get back to me.

It will be an eye opening experience for you.

I recommend you start with the books linked in the original post.


102 posted on 01/24/2012 7:13:50 AM PST by Brian Kopp DPM
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 101 | View Replies]

To: Dr. Brian Kopp
I am quite familiar with the subject - apparently you are completely ignorant of the reality on the ground, history, and have a rather minority view among those who study demographics.

Among those who study demographics there is a universal acknowledgment that human population in increasing, and will continue to increase.

Because you don't seem to follow math very well I will explain something to you. 3.5 billion people need a birth rate roughly TWICE what 7 billion people have, in order to add a billion people to their population in the same amount of time.

Because we now have 7 billion people, rather than 6, a declining birth rate will STILL add another billion people faster than 6 billion at a higher birth rate added another billion.

I don't remember, back when there were only 6 billion people on Earth rather than 7, MISSING them in an economic sense.

Similarly, if the illegal population of these United States were to be economically encouraged to go home, it would not be an economic blight upon the USA because of their ‘missing’ population.

How do you reconcile your out of the mainstream view with the economic blight of those nations with huge birth rates, and the economic blight we suffer because of illegal immigration?

Shouldn't all those extra people provide an economic boon? Why don't they?

103 posted on 01/24/2012 7:27:27 AM PST by allmendream (Tea Party did not send the GOP to D.C. to negotiate the terms of our surrender to socialism.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 102 | View Replies]

To: allmendream


              IS POPULATION GROWTH A DRAG ON ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT?

                                 Julian L. Simon1

                  This is the economic history of humanity in a nutshell:
             From 2 million or 200,000 or 20,000 or 2,000 years ago until
             the 18th Century there was slow growth in population, almost
             no increase in health or decrease in mortality, slow growth
             in the availability of natural resources (but not increased
             scarcity), increase in wealth for a few, and mixed effects
             on the environment.  Since then there has been rapid growth
             in population due to spectacular decreases in the death
             rate, rapid growth in resources, widespread increases in
             wealth, and an unprecedently clean and beautiful living
             environment in many parts of the world along with a degraded
             environment in the poor and socialist parts of the world.

             That is, more people and more wealth has correlated
             with more (rather than less) resources and a cleaner
             environment - just the opposite of what Malthusian
             theory leads one to believe.


             For many years until recently, it was thought by

        "development economists" that population growth is a drag upon

        economic development in poor countries.  And even after a

        considerable shift in professional opinion in the 1980s,

        population growth is commonly believed to hinder development.

        This belief was the underlying assumption at the United Nations'

        World Population Conference in Cairo in 1994 just as it was at

        previous  World Population Conferences and as it probably will be

        again at the World Population Conference in 2004, irrespective of

        respectable scientific opinion.

             In accord with the earlier professional opinion, since the

        early 1960's official institutions such as the U.S. State Depart-

        ment's Agency for International Development (AID), the World

        Bank, and the United Nations Fund for Population Activities

        (UNFPA), have acted on the assumption that population growth is

        the key determinant of economic development.  This belief has

        misdirected attention away from the central factor in a country's

        economic development: its economic and political system.  This

        misplaced attention has resulted in unsound economic advice being

        given to developing nations.  It also has caused (or allowed) the

        misdiagnosis of such world development problems as supplies of

        natural resources, starving children, illiteracy, pollution, and

        slow growth.

             From the 1970s through the date of this publication, the

        U.S. government directly and indirectly has been spending

        hundreds of milions of dollars annually in foreign assistance for

        family planning and other programs aimed at slowing population

        growth in the poorer countries.  Not only could these funds have

        been put to other purposes, but in some cases, the population

        control programs funded by U.S. taxpayers have involved coercive

        policies designed to reduce birth rates in LDCs.

             One reason that population growth has been viewed as a

        villain is that poor countries tend to have a high birth rate.

        And it seems "common sense" that if fewer babies were born, there

        would be more of the supposedly fixed quantities of food and

        housing to go around.  Furthermore, in earlier decades most

        economists did not have another persuasive explanation of growth

        and wealth.  Population growth became the villain by default.

             The belief that population growth slows economic development

        is not a wrong but harmless idea.  Rather, it has been the basis

        for inhumane programs of coercion and the denial of personal

        liberty in one of the most valued choices a family can make --

        the number of children that it wishes to bear and raise.  Also,

        harm has been done to the U. S. as donor of foreign aid, over and

        beyond the funds themselves, by way of money laundered through

        international organizations that comes back to finance domestic

        population propaganda organizations, and so on.  This topic has

        been addressed in detail elsewhere (Simon, 1981, Chapters 21, 22)

             This paper makes two points.  First, there is persuasive

        explanation for why some countries grow faster than others, and

        the explanation has nothing to do with population growth.  This

        factor leaves little room for population growth to be the cause

        of slow growth.  Second, there is persuasive direct statistical

        evidence that population growth is not associated negatively with

        economic development in the short or intermediate run, and may

        well be a positive influence in the long run.  A corollary is

        that a more dense population does not hamper population growth.

             In the very short run, additional people are an added

        burden.  But under conditions of freedom, population growth poses

        less of a problem in the short run, and brings many more benefits

        in the long run, than under conditions of government control.


           THE ROLE OF THE SOCIO-ECONOMIC SYSTEM IN ECONOMIC PROGRESS

             If there is another convincing explanation for the bulk of

        differences among countries in economic growth, then the

        likelihood that population growth is an important drag on

        development is logically diminished.  The most powerful evidence

        explaining the rate of economic progress is found in the

        aggregate statistics which relate economic-political systems to

        their rates of economic growth.

             Raymond Gastil (annual) categorizes the systems.  He grades

        each nation on three measures of liberty:  political, civil, and

        economic.  Economic liberty comprises two sub-measures -- the

        extent of government intervention in markets, and the level of

        personal economic liberty.

             Gerald Scully (1988) related Gastil's data to economic

        results.  Allowing for other relevant factors, he finds a strong

        relationship between each of the three liberty variables and the

        rate of economic growth during 1960 to 1980 among 115 nations.

        And when he folds all three measures of liberty into a single

        variable, he finds that nations characterized as "politically

        open, individual rights, and free market" had an average growth

        rate per capita of 2.73 percent, whereas those characterized as

        "politically closed, state rights, and command [economy]" had an

        average growth rate of 0.91 percent.  This is a huge difference

        in performance.

             Gary Becker (1989) deepens confidence in Scully's result

        with a study along the same lines which finds that "political

        democracy" is positively related to economic growth.  And using a

        somewhat different methods, Keith Marsden arrived at much the

        same now-solid conclusion.

             The results in China's agricultural sector before and after

        the 1979-1981 period are an important illustration of the

        decisive effect of the political and economic structure upon

        economic development.  Under a system of collective production

        where there was little incentive for farmers to work hard and

        take risks, but great incentive for them to loaf on the job, food

        production stagnated in the years before 1979.  The combination

        of bad weather and The Great Leap Forward during the years 1959

        to 1961 caused production to fall so drastically that 30 million

        people died of starvation.  This was certainly the worst food-

        production performance of any country in modern times, and

        perhaps the worst ever.

             Then the Chinese government undertook the largest and

        fastest social movement of all time.  Within a period of three

        years, the 700 million people in the agricultural sector shifted

        from collective enterprise to individual enterprise, and

        agriculture became the largest "private" sector in the world, by

        far.  And since then Chinese agricultural production has

        skyrocketed.  Per capita food production showed almost no

        increase from 1950 to 1978.  But starting with the reform in

        1979, per capita production almost doubled by 1985, a truly

        incredible increase, with continued growth since then and no

        limit in  sight.  The visitor to China is confronted with

        bounteous appetizing food on every streetcorner, it seems, in the

        sharpest contrast to the situation in the former Soviet Union.

             One may wonder whether the Chinese agricultural turnaround

        was "just" an isolated event, and could have other causes than

        the shift in social system.  We may therefore consult a wider

        range of experience, though using prose accounts rather than

        statistical analysis.  Sven Rydenfelt analyzed the experience of

        fifteen socialist countries on four continents and finds a

        pervasive pattern of economic failure.  However, each of these

        cases also can be "explained" on the basis of its individual

        culture rather than its socialist system.

             Most vivid is the eyeball evidence.  One need only travel by

        bus across the Karelian peninsula which was wholly within Finland

        until World War II.  The part that is still within Finland has

        incomparably better roads and more modern shops and facilities

        than the part that is now within the Soviet Union.  Or drive from

        West Berlin to East Berlin.  Or take the train from the mainland

        portion of Hong Kong across the border to China.  The differences

        in favor of a free-enterprise private-property society are

        literally unmistakable for all who are not entirely masked by

        ideological blinders.

             Evidence that is both dramatic and powerful statistically

        arises from the unique experiment that the world's political

        system created following World War II.  Three nations - Germany,

        Korea, and China - were split into socialist and non-socialist

        parts, producing three pairs of countries whose members began

        with the same culture and language and history.  The members of

        the pairs also had much the same standard of living when they

        split apart, and the same birth rates.  Their subsequent

        histories enable us to determine the effect of economic system,

        because it is the only relevant variable that differs between the

        elements of each pair.  These comparisons constitute a useful

        combination of scientific rigor with ease of communication and

        understanding.  (Similar comparisons can be made with such

        neighboring countries, one socialist and one capitalist, such as

        Austria with Czechoslovakia.)

             Other than the case of Korea, which will provide a

        continuing laboratory example, the results are now in and are

        known to all.  (For a full display of the data, please see the

        predecessor to this essay, Simon, 1990).

             Standard measures of development that show the huge

        differences in results with different socio-economic systems

        include:

        Output Per Person

             Whether per person is measured by either the exchange-rate

        method or the purchasing-power-parity method, the result of the

        comparison is the same.  The pairs began with roughly-equal

        incomes after World War II.  In each case, by the 1990s the

        communist country had a much lower income.  Taiwan's income is

        three or four times as high as China's, S. Korea's about twice as

        N. Korea's, and W. Germany's was vastly higher than E. Germany's.

             Differences in product quality are not reflected in the

        standard statisticaly comparisons, but are important.  In East

        Germany the four-cylinder primitive Trabant was almost the only

        car one can buy.  A person had to work 3,807 hours to earn enough

        to purchase a Trabant, whereas in West Germany 607 hours work

        paid for a much better car.  And people had to wait in line for

        ten years to get a car in East Germany.

             A refrigerator required 293 hours of work in East Germany,

        but only 40 hours in West Germany; a suit required 67 hours of

        work, versus 13 hours in West Germany.

             Only 36 percent of housing facilities in East Germany

        hadcentral heating, 60 percent an indoor toilet, and 68 percent a

        bath or shower.  In West Germany the corresponding percentages

        were 70 percent, 95 percent, and 92 percent.

        Life and Health

             Goods only have value if one is alive to enjoy them.

        Concerning the number of years that a newly-born person could

        expect to live, the free-enterprise countries did better in each

        pair, though each pair started out with much the same life-

        expectancy after World War II.  The same is true of the results

        for infant mortality.  These results are particularly interesting

        because public health had been one of the more-successful

        activities of socialized countries.  And indeed, for a while the

        differences between the members of pairs were small. But

        throughout Eastern Europe, life expectancy actually fell in the

        last decades of the socialist experiment, and infant mortality

        has increased. This reversal is not yet well-understood, but it

        certainly stemmed from a congeries of characteristics of a

        publicly-run health system, and from the general poverty of

        socialized economies.

        Proportion of the Labor Force in Agriculutre

             The best long-run indicator of the extent of development of

        a society is the proportion of the labor force that is employed

        in agriculture.  The fewer the people that are needed to feed the

        population, the larger the number of people that can be employed

        in providing other goods.  The countries with freer markets --

        including freer labor markets and freer agriculture -- needed

        fewer people to feed the rest.

        Economic Infra-structure

             The number of telephones is a good measure of the

        development of a country's infra-structure, and more particularly

        its crucial communications infra-structure.  The communist

        countries lagged behind the development of the market-oriented

        countries.

             These data for the paired-country experiments in political

        and economic systems provide evidence that is well-grounded

        scientifically as well as dramatic and easily-understood.  They

        prove that the socio-economic system is the main determinant of

        economic growth.  There is little other variation in

        developmental rates that might be explained by population

        growth.


           POPULATION GROWTH AND DENSITY AS INFLUENCES ON DEVELOPMENT

             The paired-country data corroborate a larger body of other

        scientific studies which show that population growth and density

        do not hamper development.  The first line in Table 1 shows that

        in each split-country case the centrally-planned communist

        country began with less population "pressure," as measured by

        density per square kilometer, compared to the paired market-

        directed non-communist country.  And the communist and non-

        communist countries in each pair also started with much the same

        birth rates and population growth rates.  There is certainly no

        evidence here which suggests that population growth or density

        influences the rate of economic development.    Contrary to the

        idea that population growth necessarily inhibits economic growth,

        the free market countries, each with faster expansion in

        population, experienced more rapid development -- on a per capita

        basis -- than their neighboring socialist nations.  If anything,

        the data show that more people have a positive effect on

        development.

             The most powerful evidence on the relationship between the

        rate of population growth and the rate of economic growth are the

        global correlations.  There now exist perhaps a score of

        competent statistical studies, beginning in 1967 with an analysis

        by Simon Kuznets covering the few countries for which data are

        available over the past century, and also analyses by Kuznets

        (1967) and Richard Easterlin (1967) of the data covering many

        countries since World War II.  The basic method is to gather data

        on each country's rate of population growth and its rate of

        economic growth, and then to examine whether -- looking at all

        the data in the sample together -- the countries with high

        population growth rates have economic growth rates lower than

        average, and countries with low population growth rates have

        economic growth rates higher than average.  Various writers have

        used a variety of samples of countries, and they have employed an

        impressive battery of ingenious statistical techniques to allow

        for other factors that might also be affecting the outcome.

             The clear-cut consensus of this body of research is that

        faster population growth is not associated with slower economic

        growth.  Of course one can adduce cases of countries that

        seemingly are exceptions to the pattern.  It is the genius of

        statistical inference, however, to enable us to draw valid

        generalizations from samples that contain such wide variations in

        behavior.  The exceptions can be useful in alerting us to

        possible avenues for further analysis, but as long as they are

        only exceptions, they do not prove that the generalization is not

        meaningful or useful.

             It has been suggested (e.g. by Roger Conner, 1984) that the

        studies showing the absence of a relationship between the

        population rate and the economic growth rate also demonstrate

        that additional people do not imply a higher standard of living

        in the long run. That is, because these studies do not show a

        positive correlation, one is said to make claims beyond the

        evidence if one says that over the very long sweep of human

        history a larger population in the world (or perhaps, in what is

        the developed part of the world at any moment) has meant faster

        rates of increase of technology and the standard of living.

             It is indeed the case that the existing body of empirical

        studies does not prove that fast population growth in the more-

        developed world as a whole increases per person income.  But this

        is not inconsistent with the proposition that more people do

        raise the standard of living in the long run.  Recall that the

        studies mentioned above do not refer to the very long run, but

        rather usually cover only a quarter of a century, or a century at

        most.  The main negative effects of population growth occur

        during perhaps the first quarter or half of a century so that, if

        these effects are important, the empirical studies referred to

        should reveal them.  These shorter-run effects upon the standard

        of living include the public costs of raising children -- schools

        and hospitals are the main examples -- and the costs of providing

        additional production capital for the additional persons in the

        work force.  The absence of an observed negative effect upon

        economic growth in the statistical measures therefore is enough

        to imply that in the very long run more people have a positive

        net effect.  This is because the most important positive effects

        of additional people -- improvement of productivity through both

        the contribution of new ideas, and also the learning-by-doing

        consequent upon increased production volume -- happen in the long

        run, and are cumulative.  To put it differently, the statistical

        measurements of the relationship of population growth to economic

        growth are biased in favor of showing the shorter-run effects,

        which tend to be negative, and not showing the longer-run

        effects, which tend to be positive.  If such negative effects do

        not appear, one may assume that an unbiased measure of the total

        effect would reveal a positive effect of population growth upon

        economic growth.

             There is still another reason why the studies mentioned

        above do not imply an absence of positive effect in the long run:

        They focus on the process of population growth.  If we look

        instead at the attained level of population -- that is, the

        population density as measured by the number of persons per

        square mile, say -- we see a somewhat different result.  Studies

        of MDC's are lacking.  But Everett Hagen (l975) and Charles

        Kindleberger (l965) show visually, and Simon and Roy Gobin (l979)

        show in multivariate regressions, that in LDC's higher population

        density is associated with higher rates of economic growth; this

        effect may be strongest at low densities, but there is no

        evidence that the effect reverses at high densities.  Again, the

        statistical evidence directly contradicts the common-sense

        conventional wisdom.  That is, if you make a chart with

        population density on the horizontal axis and either the income

        level or the rate of change of income on the vertical axis, you

        will see that higher density is associated with better rather

        than poorer economic results.

             The data showing a positive effect of density upon economic

        growth constitute indirect proof of a positive long-run effect of

        population growth upon economic growth, because density changes

        occur very slowly, and therefore the data pick up the very-long-

        run effects as well as the short run effects.3

             Hong Kong is a vivid example of this phenomenon.  In the

        1940's and 1950's, it seemed impossible for Hong Kong to surmount

        its problems -- huge masses of impoverished people without jobs,

        total lack of exploitable natural resources, more refugees

        pouring across the border each day.  Today, Hong Kong enjoys high

        living standards, low unemployment, an astounding collection of

        modern high-rise apartments and office buildings, and one of the

        world's most modern transportation systems.  Hong Kong starkly

        demonstrates that a very dense concentration of human beings does

        not prevent comfortable existence and exciting economic

        expansion, as long as the economic system gives individuals the

        freedom to exercise their talents and to take advantage of

        opportunities.  And the experience of Singapore demonstrates that

        Hong Kong is not unique.

             Check for yourself: Fly over Hong Kong -- just a few decades

        ago a place seemingly without prospects because of insoluble

        resource problems -- and you will marvel at the skyline of

        buildings.  Take a ride on its excellent smooth-flowing highways

        for an hour or two, and you will realize that a very dense

        concentration of human beings does not prevent comfortable

        existence and a rapid rate of economic growth.2

             At this point the question frequently arises:  If more

        people cause there to be more ideas and knowledge, and hence

        higher productivity and income, why are not India and China the

        richest nations in the world?  Let us put aside the matter that

        size in terms of population within national boundaries was not

        very meaningful in earlier centuries when national integration

        was much looser than it is now.  There remains the question,

        however, why so many human beings in those countries produced so

        little change in the last few hundred years.  Yes, low education

        of most people in China and India prevents them from producing

        knowledge and change (though we should note the very large, in

        absolute terms, contemporary scientific establishments in those

        two countries.)  But though education may account for much of the

        present situation, it does not account nearly as well for the

        differences between the West and the East over the five centuries

        or so up to, say, l850.

             William McNeill (l963), Eric Jones (1981) and others have

        suggested that over several centuries the relative instability of

        social and economic life in Europe, compared to China and India,

        helps account for the emergence of modern growth in the West

        rather than in the East.  Instability implies economic

        disequilibria, which (as Theodore Schultz [1975] reminds us)

        imply exploitable opportunities which then lead to augmented

        effort.  (Such disequilibria also cause the production of new

        knowledge, it would seem.)

              The hypothesis that the combination of a person's wealth

        and opportunities affect the person's exertion of effort may go

        far in explaining the phenomenon at hand.  Ceteris paribus, the

        less wealth a person has, the greater the person's drive to take

        advantage of economic opportunities.  The village millions in

        India and China certainly have had plenty of poverty to stimulate

        them.  But they have lacked opportunities because of the static

        and immobile nature of their village life.  In contrast,

        villagers in Western Europe apparently had more mobility, less

        stability, and more exposure to cross-currents of all kinds.

             Just why Europe should have been so much more open than

        India and China is a question that historians answer with

        conjectures about religion, smallness of countries with

        consequent competition and instability, and a variety of other

        special conditions.  This matter need not be pursued here.  But

        we should at least mention Lal's 1988 book on India's economic

        development over thousands of years, which suggests that it was

        only the rapid population growth starting around 1921 which

        cracked the "cake of custom" and the Hindu caste system, and

        caused the mobility which allowed India to begin modern

        development.

             Most (if not all) historians of the period (e.g. Nef, 1958/

        1963; Gimpel, 1976) agree that the period of rapid population

        growth from before AD 1000 to the beginning of the middle of the

        1300s was a period of extraordinary intellectual fecundity.  It

        was also a period of great dynamism generally, as seen in the

        extraordinary cathedral building boom.  But during the period of

        depopulation due to the plague (starting with the Black Death

        cataclysm) and perhaps to climatic changes from the middle 1300s

        (though the change apparently began earlier at the time of major

        famines around 1315-17, and perhaps even earlier, when there also

        was a slowing or cessation of population growth due to other

        factors) until perhaps the 1500s, historians agree that

        intellectual and social vitality waned.

             Henri Pirenne's magisterial analysis (1925/1969) of this

        period depends heavily upon population growth and size.  Larger

        absolute numbers were the basis for increased trade and

        consequent growth in cities, which in turn strongly influenced

        the creation of a more articulated exchange economy in place of

        the subsistence economy of the manor.  And according to Pirenne,

        growth in population also loosened the bonds of the serf in the

        city and thereby contributed to an increase in human liberty

        (though the causes of the end of serfdom are a subject of much

        controversy).

             A corollary, of course, is that once the people in the East

        lose the shackles of static village life and get some education,

        their poverty (absolute and relative) will drive them to an

        extraordinary explosion of creative effort.  The happenings in

        Taiwan and Korea in recent decades suggest that this is already

        beginning to occur.

             This explanation would seem more systematic, and more

        consistent with the large body of economic thought, than are

        explanations in terms of Confucianism or of particular cultures,

        just as the Protestant-ethic explanation for the rise of the West

        (discussion of which goes back at least to David Hume) now seems

        unpersuasive in the face of religious counter-examples (e.g. the

        Catholic Ibo in Nigeria) and shifts in behavior of Protestant

        nations.

             Though the statistical studies together with the historical

        analogies would seem to constitute persuasive evidence of the

        positive long-run effect of additional people, experience shows

        that it is not convincing.  Perhaps a few thought experiments in

        the form of hypothetical comparisons will add conviction.

        Therefore, please ask yourself:  i) Would the world be in better

        or worse shape today if all the people who have ever lived in the

        area now called the Netherlands (or India, or China, or Portugal,

        or wherever) had never lived at all?  ii) If you were colonizing

        another planet such as the moon or Saturn, would you prefer that

        ten, or a hundred, or a thousand, or a million, or ten million

        persons were also colonizing along with you?  Under which

        condition would exploration and mapping of the resources of the

        moon take place more rapidly?  Under which condition would the

        moon be more rapidly rendered habitable so that one could travel

        safely and find accommodations and a fast-food outlet?  iii) If

        you were Robinson Crusoe, would you have preferred that the

        island were not devoid of other humans, but rather contained some

        or many others?  Under which conditions do you think that you

        would be in less fear of your life, and feel less need to erect

        fortifications and stand watch at night?  Under which conditions

        would there be a greater pool of useful skills, and of the

        manpower to build a ship and leave the island?  Would the

        "congestion" of more people outweigh the isolation of none?  iv)

        Were the Pilgrims better or worse off for the the presence of

        Native Americans in the area when they arrived?


                                   CONCLUSION

             For 25 years our institutions have mis-analyzed such world

        development problems as starving children, illiteracy, pollution,

        supplies of natural resources and slow growth.  The World Bank,

        the State Department's Aid to International Development (AID),

        The United Nations Fund for Population Activities (UNFPA) and the

        environmental organizations have asserted that the cause is

        population growth -- the population "explosion" or "bomb" or

        "plague."  This error has cost dearly.  It has directed our

        attention away from the factor that we now know is central in a

        country's economic development, its economic and political

        system.  It suggests that attention be paid to population growth

        rather than to fighting tyranny and working for economic freedom.

        This error also has led to Westerners condoning and abetting

        inhumane programs of coercion of couples to prevent them having

        children in China and elsewhere.  Perhaps the events in Eastern

        Europe in 1989 and 1990 will open minds to the irrelevance of

        population growth for intermediate-run economic development, and

        to the all-importance of the social and economic system.



        page 1/article0 catonew/July 3, 1995

                                   REFERENCES


             Bauer, P.T., Reality and Rhetoric, (Studies in the Economics

        of Development) (Cambridge:  Harvard University Press, 1984).

             Becker, Gary, "An Environment for Economic Growth", The Wall

        Street Journal, Jan. 19, 1989, p. A8

        Easterlin

             Conner, Roger, "How Immigrants Affect Americans' Living

        Standard," A Debate Between Julian Simon and Roger Conner, The

        Heritage Foundation, May 30, 1984.

             Easterlin, Richard A. 1967. Effects of population growth in

        the economic development of of developing countries.  The Annals

        of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 369:98-

        108.

             Gastil, Raymond D., Freedom in the World (Westport, Conn:

        Greenwood, yearly ), cited by Scully

        Hagen

             Hagen, Everett E. 1975. The economics of development. Home-

        wood, Ill.: Irwin.

             Jones, Eric L., The European Miracle (New York: Cambridge

        UP, 1981).

             Kasun, Jacqueline R., The War Against Population:  The

        Economics and Ideology of World Population Control (Ottawa, Ill:

        Jameson Books, 1986).

             Kelley, Allen,  and Robert Schmidt, "Population and Income

        Change", World Bank Discussion Paper 249, 1994.

             Kindleberger, Charles P.  Economic Development.  2nd Edition

        (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1965)

             Krueger, Anne O., "Aid in the Development Process," The

        World Bank Research Observer, l, January, 1986.

                  Kuznets, Simon, "Population and economic growth".

        Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society 11:,  1967.

        170-93.

             Lal, Deepak, The Hindue Equilibrium: Cultural Stability and

        Economic Stagnation:  India 1500 BC-1980 AD (New York:  Oxford:

        Clarendon Press, 1988).

             Keith Marsden, "Why Asia Boomed and Africa Busted," WSJ,

        June 3, 1985, op ed page.

             McNeill, W. H., The Rise of the West - A History of the

        Human Community (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press,

        1963).

             Nef, John V., Western Civilization Since the Renaissance

        (New York: Harper and Row, 1950/1963).

             Pirenne, Henri, Medieval Cities (Princeton: Princeton

        University Press, 1925/1969).

             Repetto, Robert, "Why Doesn't Julian Simon Believe His Own

        Research?", Letter to the Editor, The Washington Post, Nov. 2,

        1985, p. A 21.

             Schultz, Theodore W., "The Value of the Ability to Deal with

        Disequilibria'," in Journal of Economic Literature, 1975,

        pp. 827-46.

             Schultz, Theodore W., Investing in People  (Chicago:  U. of

        Chicago Press, 1981)

             Scully, Gerald W., "Liberty and Economic Progress", Journal

        of Economic Growth, Vol 3, Nov., 1988, pp. 3-10;

             Scully, Gerald W., "The Institutional Framework and Economic

        Development", Journal of Political Economy, Vol 96, June, 1988,

        pp. 652-662.]

             Rydenfelt, Sven,  A Pattern for Failure (New York:  Harcourt

        Brace Jovanovich, 1983)

             Simon, Julian L., "The Concept of Causality in Economics,"

        Kyklos, Vol. 23, Fasc. 2, 1970, pp. 226-254.

             Simon, Julian L.,  The Ultimate Resource (Princeton; PUP,

        1981, second edition forthcoming)

             Simon, Julian L., Population and Development Review, June,

        1989

             Simon, Julian L., , and Roy Gobin.  "The relationship

        between population and economic growth in LDC's.  In Julian L.

        Simon and Julie deVanzo, eds., Research in Population Economics.

        Vol. 2.  (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press, 1979)



        page 2/article0 catonew/July 3, 1995

                                   FOOTNOTES



             1In this paper I draw freely upon a variety of Simon's other

        writings that have touched upon the subjects at hand, especially

        "Why Do We Still Think Babies Create Poverty", Washington Post,

        October 12, 1985; and "The War on People", Challenge, March-

        April, 1985, pp. 50-53.  I appreciate comments by Jim Dorn, David

        Boaz and Theodore W. Schultz.  Stephen Moore helped prepare the

        tabular material.

             2Hong Kong is a special thrill for me because I first saw it

        in 1955 when I went ashore from a U.S. Navy destroyer.  At the

        time I felt great pity for the thousands of people who slept

        every night on the sidewalks or on small boats.  It then seemed

        clear to me, as it must have to almost every observer, that it

        would be impossible for Hong Kong to surmount its problems --

        huge masses of impoverished people without jobs, total lack of

        exploitable natural resources, more refugees pouring across the

        border each day.  And it is this sort of picture that has

        convinced many persons that a place is "overpopulated" and should

        cut its birth rate (e.g. Ehrlich at the beginning of The

        Population Bomb).  But upon returning in 1983, I saw bustling

        crowds of healthy, vital people full of hope and energy.  No

        cause for pity now.

              3It may at first seem preposterous that greater population

        density might lead to better economic results.  This is the

        equivalent of saying that if all Americans moved east of the

        Mississippi, we might not be the poorer for it.  Upon reflection,

        this proposition is not as unlikely as it sounds.  The main loss

        involved in such a move would be huge amounts of farmland, and

        though the United States is a massive producer and exporter of

        farm goods, agriculture is not crucial to the economy.  Less than

        3% of U.S. income comes from agriculture, and less than 3% of the

        U. S. working population is engaged in that industry.  The

        capitalized value of all U.S. farm land is just a bit more than a

        tenth of just one year's national income, so even if the U.S.

        were to lose all of it, the loss would equal only about one

        year's expenditures upon liquor, cigarettes, and the like.  On

        the other hand, such a change would bring about major benefits in

        shortening transportation and communication distances, a factor

        which has been important in Japan's ability to closely coordinate

        its industrial operations in such a fashion as to reduce costs of

        inventory and transportation.  Additionally, greater population

        concentration forces social changes in the direction of a greater

        degree of organization, changes which may be costly in the short

        run but in the long run increase a society's ability to reach its

        economic and social objectives.  If we were still living at the

        population density of, say, ten thousand years ago, we would have

        none of the vital complex social and economic apparatuses that

        are the backbone of our society.




        page 3/article0 catonew/July 3, 1995


        Wall Street Journal, Sept 4, 1987, p. 1, re the two Germanies

        On mark exchange rate:  Wash Post, Nov 15, 89 p.  A26




        page 4/article0 catonew/July 3, 1995



104 posted on 01/24/2012 7:32:54 AM PST by Brian Kopp DPM
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 103 | View Replies]

To: allmendream
How do you reconcile your out of the mainstream view

Global warming was a mainstream view till not too long ago too.

105 posted on 01/24/2012 7:35:06 AM PST by Brian Kopp DPM
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 103 | View Replies]

To: Dr. Brian Kopp
So does illegal immigration into the USA provide an economic boon from all the excess population?

Yes or no?

If not, why not?

Why don't all the extra children born into poverty provide an economic boon to the nations with absurdly high birth rates?

How do you reconcile your out of the mainstream view with this reality?

Global warming was a mainstream view until data demolished it.

Where is the data undercutting the widely reported and almost universally acknowledged EXPANDING human population?

Even you admit we may well climb to NINE BILLION PEOPLE!

That is both much more likely and a graver threat to human well being than your mythical decline in human population, based upon an innumerate assumption that the slightly declining birth rates of 7 billion people will lead to demographic collapse, instead of rapidly approaching 8 billion people and climbing.

106 posted on 01/24/2012 8:32:18 AM PST by allmendream (Tea Party did not send the GOP to D.C. to negotiate the terms of our surrender to socialism.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 105 | View Replies]

To: allmendream
"The evidence of 7 BILLION PEOPLE rapidly climbing to 8 and even 9 BILLION PEOPLE."

Hmmm OK so 9 Billion people will over populate the Earth?

I have a question for you. How many states (of the USA) would 9 Billion cover if we all got together for one of those aerial group shots? (shoulder to Shoulder back to front like in a group photo)

107 posted on 01/24/2012 8:39:31 AM PST by Mad Dawgg (If you're going to deny my 1st Amendment rights then I must proceed to the 2nd one...)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 101 | View Replies]

To: allmendream

                          MORE PEOPLE, GREATER WEALTH,

                      MORE RESOURCES, HEALTHIER ENVIRONMENT

                                 Julian L. Simon


                                   INTRODUCTION

                  This is the economic history of humanity in a nutshell:

        From 2 million or 200,000 or 20,000 or 2,000 years ago until the

        18th Century there was slow growth in population, almost no

        increase in health or decrease in mortality, slow growth in the

        availability of natural resources (but not increased scarcity),

        increase in wealth for a few, and mixed effects on the

        environment.  Since then there has been rapid growth in

        population due to spectacular decreases in the death rate, rapid

        growth in resources, widespread increases in wealth, and an

        unprecedently clean and beautiful living environment in many

        parts of the world along with a degraded environment in the poor

        and socialist parts of the world.

             That is, more people and more wealth has correlated with

        more (rather than less) resources and a cleaner environment -

        just the opposite of what Malthusian theory leads one to believe.

        The task before us is to make sense of these mind-boggling happy

        trends.

             The current gloom-and-doom about a "crisis" of our

        environment is all wrong on the scientific facts.  Even the U. S.

        Environmental Protection Agency acknowledges that U.S. air and

        our water have been getting cleaner rather than dirtier in the

        past few decades.  Every agricultural economist knows that the

        world's population has been eating ever-better since World War

        II.  Every resource economist knows that all natural resources

        have been getting more available rather than more scarce, as

        shown by their falling prices over the decades and centuries.

        And every demographer knows that the death rate has been falling

        all over the world - life expectancy almost tripling in the rich

        countries in the past two centuries, and almost doubling in the

        poor countries in just the past four decades.

             The picture also is now clear that population growth does

        not hinder economic development.  In the 1980s there was a

        complete reversal in the consensus of thinking of population

        economists about the effects of more people.  In 1986, the

        National Research Council and the National Academy of Sciences

        completely overturned its "official" view away from the earlier

        worried view expressed in 1971.  It noted the absence of any

        statistical evidence of a negative connection between population

        increase and economic growth.  And it said that "The scarcity of

        exhaustible resources is at most a minor restraint on economic

        growth".

             This U-turn by the scientific consensus of experts on

        the subject has gone unacknowledged by the press, the anti-

        natalist environmental organizations, and the agencies that

        foster population control abroad.

             Here is my central assertion:  Almost every economic and

        social change or trend points in a positive direction, as

        long as we view the matter over a reasonably long period of

        time.

             For proper understanding of the important aspects of an

        economy we should look at the long-run trends.  But the short-run

        comparisons - between the sexes, age groups, races, political

        groups, which are usually purely relative - make more news.  To

        repeat, just about every important long-run measure of human

        welfare shows improvement over the decades and centuries, in the

        United States as well as in the rest of the world.  And there is

        no persuasive reason to believe that these trends will not

        continue indefinitely.

             Would I bet on it?  For sure.  I'll bet a week's or month's

        pay - anything I win goes to pay for more research - that just

        about any trend pertaining to material human welfare will improve

        rather than get worse.  You pick the comparison and the year.

                                    THE FACTS

             Let's quickly review a few data on how human life has been

        doing, beginning with the all-important issue, life itself.

        The Conquest of Too-early Death

             The most important and amazing demographic fact --  the

        greatest human achievement in history, in my view - - is the

        decrease in the world's death rate.  Figure 1 portrays the

        history human life expectancy at birth.  It took thousands of

        years to increase life expectancy at birth from just over 20

        years to the high '20's about 1750.  Then about 1750 life

        expectancy in the richest countries suddenly took off and tripled

        in about two centuries. In just the past two centuries, the

        length of life you could expect for your baby or yourself in the

        advanced countries jumped from less than 30 years to perhaps 75

        years.  What greater event has humanity witnessed than this

        conquest of premature death in the rich countries?  It is this

        decrease in the death rate that is the cause of there being a

        larger world population nowadays than in former times.

                                     Figure 1

             Then starting well after World War II, the length of life

        you could expect in the poor countries has leaped upwards by

        perhaps fifteen or even twenty years since the l950s, caused by

        advances in agriculture, sanitation, and medicine.  (See Figure

        2)

                                     Figure 2

             Let's put it differently.  In the 19th century the planet

        Earth could sustain only one billion people.  Ten thousand years

        ago, only 4 million could keep themselves alive.  Now, 5 billion

        people are living longer and more healthily than ever before, on

        average.  The increase in the world's population represents our

        victory over death.

             Here arises a crucial issue of interpretation:  One would

        expect lovers of humanity to jump with joy at this triumph of

        human mind and organization over the raw killing forces of

        nature.  Instead, many lament that there are so many people alive

        to enjoy the gift of life.  Even regret death rate. And it is

        this worry that leads them to approve the Indonesian, Chinese and

        other inhumane programs of coercion and denial of personal

        liberty in one of the most precious choices a family can make --

        the number of children that it wishes to bear and raise.

        The Decreasing Scarcity of Natural Resources

             Throughout history, the supply of natural resources always

        has worried people.  Yet the data clearly show that natural

        resource scarcity -- as measured by the economically-meaningful

        indicator of cost or price -- has been decreasing rather than

        increasing in the long run for all raw materials, with only

        temporary exceptions from time to time.  That is, availability

        has been increasing.  Consider copper, which is representative

        of all the metals.  In Figure 3 we see the price relative to

        wages since 1801.  The cost of a ton is only about a tenth now

        of what it was two hundred years ago.

                                     Figure 3

             This trend of falling prices of copper has been going on for

        a very long time.  In the l8th century B.C.E. in Babylonia under

        Hammurabi -- almost 4000 years ago -- the price of copper was

        about a thousand times its price in the U.S. now relative to

        wages.  At  the time of the Roman Empire the price was about a

        hundred times the present price.

             In Figure 4 we see the price of copper relative to the

        consumer price index.  Everything that we buy - pens, shirts,

        tires - has been getting cheaper over the years because we know

        how to make them cheaper, especially during the past 200 years.

        Even so, the extraordinary fact is that natural resources have

        been getting cheaper even faster than consumer goods.

                                     Figure 4

             So by any measure, natural resources have getting more

        available rather than more scarce.

             Regarding oil, the shocking price rises during the 1970s and

        1980s were not caused by growing scarcity in the world supply.

        And indeed, the price of petroleum in inflation-adjusted dollars

        has returned to levels about where they were before the

        politically-induced increases, and the price of of gasoline is

        about at the historic low and still falling.  Concerning energy

        in general, there is no reason to believe that the supply of

        energy is finite, or that the price of energy will not continue

        its long-run decrease forever.  I realize that it sounds weird to

        say that the supply of energy is not finite or limited; for the

        full argument, please see my 1981 book (revised edition

        forthcoming)  (Science is only valuable when it arrives at

        knowledge different than common sense.)

             Food is an especially important resource.  The evidence is

        particularly strong for food that we are on a benign trend

        despite rising population.  The long-run  price of food relative

        to wages is now only perhaps a tenth as much as it was in 1800 in

        the U. S.  Even relative to consumer products the price of grain

        is down, due to increased productivity, just as with all other

        primary products.

             Famine deaths due to insufficient food supply have decreased

        even in absolute terms, let alone relative to population, in the

        past century, a matter which pertains particularly to the poor

        countries.  Per-person food consumption is up over the last 30

        years.  And there are no data showing that the bottom of the

        income scale is faring worse, or even has failed to share in the

        general improvement, as the average has improved.

             Africa's food production per person is down, but by 1994

        almost no one any longer claims that Africa's suffering

        results from a shortage of land or water or sun.  The cause of

        hunger in Africa is a combination of civil wars and

        collectivization of agriculture, which periodic droughts have

        made more murderous.

             Consider agricultural land as an example of all natural

        resources.  Though many people consider land to be a special kind

        of resource, it is subject to the same processes of human crea-

        tion as other natural resources.  The most important fact about

        agricultural land is that less and less of it is needed as the

        decades pass.  This idea is utterly counter-intuitive.  It seems

        entirely obvious that a growing world population would need

        larger amounts of farmland.  But the title of a remarkable pres-

        cient article in 1951 by Theodore Schultz tells the story:  "The

        Declining Economic Importance of Land".

             The increase in actual and potential productivity per unit

        of land have grown much faster than population, and there is

        sound reason to expect this trend to continue.  Therefore, there

        is less and less reason to worry about the supply of land.

        Though the stock of usable land seems fixed at any moment, it is

        constantly being increased - at a rapid rate in many cases - by

        the clearing of new land or reclamation of wasteland. Land also

        is constantly being enhanced by increasing the number of crops

        grown per year on each unit of land and by increasing the yield

        per crop with better farming methods and with chemical

        fertilizer. Last but not least, land is created anew where there

        was no land.

             There is only one important resource which has shown a trend
        of increasing scarcity rather than increasing abundance.  That
        resource is the most important of all -- human beings.  Yes,
        there are more people on earth now than ever before.  But if we
        measure the scarcity of people the same way that we measure the
        scarcity of other economic goods -- by how much we must pay to
        obtain their services -- we see that wages and salaries have been
        going up all over the world, in poor countries as well as in rich
        countries.  The amount that you must pay to obtain the services
        of a barber or a cook has risen in India, just as the price of a
        barber or cook -- or economist -- has risen in the United States
        over the decades.  This increase in the price of peoples'
        services is a clear indication that people are becoming more
        scarce even though there are more of us.

             About pollution now:  Surveys show that  the public believes

        that our air and water have been getting more polluted in recent

        years.  The evidence with respect to air indicates that

        pollutants have been declining, especially the  main pollutant,

        particulates.  (See Figure 5).  With respect to water, the

        proportion of monitoring sites in the U.S. with water of good

        drinkability has increased since the data began in l96l. (Figure

        6).

                                 Figures 5 and 6

             Every forecast of the doomsayers has turned out flat wrong.

        Metals, foods, and other natural resources have become more

        available rather than more scarce throughout the centuries.  The

        famous Famine 1975 forecast by the Paddock brothers -- that we

        would see millions of famine deaths in the U.S. on television in

        the 1970s -- was followed instead by gluts in agricultural

        markets.  Paul Ehrlich's primal scream about "What will we do

        when the [gasoline] pumps run dry?" was followed by gasoline

        cheaper than since the 1930's.  The Great Lakes are not dead;

        instead they offer better sport fishing than ever.  The main

        pollutants, especially the particulates which have killed people

        for years, have lessened in our cities.  (Socialist countries are

        a different and tragic environmental story, however!)

             The wrong forecasts of shortages of copper and other metals

        have not been harmless, however.  They have helped cause

        economic disasters for mining companies and for the poor

        countries which depend upon mining, by misleading them with

        unsound expectations of increased prices.  Airplane design, CAFE

        standards. Misdirected valuable resources. But nothing has

        reduced the doomsayers' credibility with the press or their

        command over the funding resources of the federal government.

             Let's dramatize these sets of changes with a single

        anecdote.  The trend toward a better life can be seen in most of

        our own families if we look.  For example, I have mild asthma.

        Recently I slept in a home where there was a dog, and in the

        middle of the night I woke with a bad cough and shortness of

        breath.  When I realized that it was caused by the dog dander, I

        took out my twelve dollar pocket inhaler, good for 3000 puffs,

        and took one puff.  Within ten minutes my lungs were clear.  A

        small miracle.  Forty years ago I would have been sleepless and

        miserable all night, and I would have had to give up the squash-

        playing that I love so much because exercise causes my worst

        asthma in the absence of an inhaler....Or diabetes.  If your

        child had diabetes a hundred years ago, you had to watch

        helplessly as the child went blind and died early.  Now

        injections, or even pills, can give the child almost as long and

        healthy a life as other children....Or glasses.  Centuries ago

        you had to give up reading when your eyes got dim as you got to

        be 40 or 50. Now you can buy magnifying glasses at the drugstore

        for nine dollars.  And you can even wear contact lenses for eye

        problems and keep your vanity intact.  Is there not some

        condition in your family that in earlier times would have been a

        lingering misery or a tragedy, that nowadays our increasing

        knowledge has rendered easily bearable?

             With respect to population growth:  A dozen competent

        statistical studies, starting in 1967 with an analysis by Nobel

        prizewinner Simon Kuznets, agree that there is no negative

        statistical relationship between economic growth and population

        growth.  There is strong reason to believe that more people have

        a positive effect in the long run.

             Population growth does not lower the standard of living -

        all the evidence agrees.  And the evidence supports the view

        that population growth raises it in the long run.

             Incidentally, it was those statistical studies that

        converted me in about 1968 from working in favor of population

        control to the point of view that I hold today.  I certainly did

        not come to my current view for any political or religious or

        ideological reason.

             The basic method is to gather data on each country's rate

        of population growth and its rate of economic growth, and then

        to examine whether -- looking at all the data in the sample

        together -- the countries with high population growth rates have

        economic growth rates lower than average, and countries with low

        population growth rates have economic growth rates higher than

        average.  All the studies agree in concluding that this is not

        so; there is no correlation between economic growth and

        population growth in the intermediate run.

             Of course one can adduce cases of countries that seemingly

        are exceptions to the pattern.  It is the genius of statistical

        inference, however, to enable us to draw valid generalizations

        from samples that contain such wide variations in behavior.  The

        exceptions can be useful in alerting us to possible avenues for

        further analysis, but as long as they are only exceptions, they

        do not prove that the generalization is not meaningful or useful.

             The research-wise person may wonder whether population

        density is a more meaningful variable than population growth.

        And indeed, such studies have been done.  And again, the

        statistical evidence directly contradicts the common-sense

        conventional wisdom.  If you make a chart with population density

        on the horizontal axis and either the income level or the rate of

        change of income on the vertical axis, you will see that higher

        density is associated with better rather than poorer economic

        results.

             Check for yourself:  Fly over Hong Kong -- just a few

        decades ago a place seemingly without prospects because of

        insoluble resource problems -- and you will marvel at the

        astounding collection of modern high-rise apartments and office

        buildings.  Take a ride on its excellent smooth-flowing highways

        for an hour or two, and you will realize that a very dense

        concentration of human beings does not prevent comfortable

        existence and exciting economic expansion -- as long as the

        economic system gives individuals the freedom to exercise their

        talents and to take advantage of opportunities.  And the

        experience of Singapore demonstrates that Hong Kong is not

        unique.  Two such examples do not prove the case, of course.  But

        these dramatic illustrations are backed by the evidence from the

        aggregate sample of countries, and hence do not mislead us.

             (Hong Kong is a special thrill for me because I first saw it

        in 1955 when I went ashore from a U. S.  Navy destroyer.  At the

        time I felt great pity for the thousands who slept every night on

        the sidewalks or on small boats.  It then seemed clear to me, as

        it must have to almost every observer, that it would be

        impossible for Hong Kong to surmount its problems -- huge masses

        of impoverished people without jobs, total lack of exploitable

        natural resources, more refugees pouring across the border each

        day.  But upon returning in 1983, I saw bustling crowds of

        healthy, vital people full of hope and energy.  No cause for pity

        now.

             The most important benefit of population size and growth is

        the increase it brings to the stock of useful  knowledge.  Minds

        matter economically as much as, or more than, hands or mouths.

        Progress is limited largely by the availability of trained

        workers.  The more people who enter our population by birth or

        immigration, the faster will be the rate of progress of our

        material and cultural civilization.

             Here we need a qualification that tends to get overlooked:

        I do not say that all is well everywhere, and I do not predict

        that all will be rosy in the future.  Children are hungry and

        sick; people live out lives of physical or intellectual poverty,

        and lack of opportunity; war or some new pollution may finish us

        off.  What I am saying is that for most relevant economic matters

        I have checked, the aggregate trends are improving rather than

        deteriorating.

             Also, I don't say that a better future happens automatically

        or without effort.  It will happen because women and men will

        struggle with problems with muscle and mind, and will probably

        overcome, as people have overcome in the past -- if the social

        and economic system gives them opportunity to do so.

                     THE EXPLANATION OF THESE AMAZING TRENDS

             Now we need some theory to explain how it can be that

        economic welfare grows along with population, rather than

        humanity being reduced to misery and poverty as population

        grows.

             The Malthusian theory of increasing scarcity, based on

        supposedly-fixed resources - the theory that the doomsayers rely

        upon - runs exactly contrary to the data over the long sweep of

        history.  Therefore it makes sense to prefer another theory.

             The theory that fits the facts very well is this: More

        people, and increased income, cause problems in the short run.

        Short-run scarcity raises prices.  This presents opportunity, and

        prompts the search for solutions.  In a free society, solutions

        are eventually found.  And in the long run the new developments

        leave us better off than if the problems had not arisen.

             To put it differently, in the short-run, more consumers mean

        less of the fixed available stock of goods to be divided among

        more people.  And more workers laboring with the same fixed

        current stock of capital mean that there will be less output per

        worker.  The latter effect, known as "the law of diminishing

        returns," is the essence of Malthus's theory as he first set it

        out.

             But if the resources with which people work are not fixed

        over the period being analyzed, then the Malthusian logic of

        diminishing returns does not apply.  And the plain fact is that,

        given some time to adjust to shortages, the resource base does

        not remain fixed.  People create more resources of all kinds.

             When we take a long-run view, the picture is different, and

        considerably more complex, than the simple short-run view of more

        people implying lower average income.  In the very long run, more

        people almost surely imply more available resources and a  higher

        income for everyone.

             I suggest you test this idea against your own knowledge:  Do

        you think that our standard of living would be as high as it is

        now if the population had never grown from about four million

        human beings perhaps ten thousand years ago?  I don't think we'd

        now have electric light or gas heat or autos or penicillin or

        travel to the moon or our present life expectancy of over seventy

        years at birth in rich countries, in comparison to the life

        expectancy of 20 to 25 years at birth in earlier eras, if

        population had not grown to its present numbers.

             Consider this example of the process by which people wind

        up with increasing availability rather than decreasing

        availability of resources.  England was full of alarm in the

        l600's at an impending shortage of energy due to the defor-

        estation of the country for firewood.  People feared a scarcity

        of fuel for both heating and for the iron industry.  This

        impending scarcity led to the development of coal.

            Then in the mid-l800's the English came to worry  about an

        impending coal crisis.  The great English economist, Jevons,

        calculated that a shortage of coal would bring England's industry

        to a standstill by l900; he carefully assessed that oil could

        never make a decisive difference.  Triggered by the impending

        scarcity of coal (and of whale oil, whose story comes next)

        ingenious profit-minded people developed oil into a more

        desirable fuel than coal ever was.  And in l990 we find England

        exporting both coal and oil.

             Another element in the story:  Because of increased demand

        due to population growth and increased income, the price of whale

        oil for lamps jumped in the l840's, and the U.S. Civil War pushed

        it even higher, leading to a whale oil "crisis."  This provided

        incentive for enterprising people to discover and produce

        substitutes.  First came oil from rapeseed, olives, linseed, and

        camphene oil from pine trees. Then inventors learned how to get

        coal oil from coal.  Other ingenious persons produced kerosene

        from the rock oil that seeped to the surface, a product so

        desirable that its price then rose from $.75 a gallon to $2.00.

        This high price stimulated enterprisers to focus on the supply of

        oil, and finally Edwin L. Drake brought in his famous well in

        Titusville, Pennsylvania.  Learning how to refine the oil took a

        while.  But in a few years there were hundreds of small refiners

        in the U.S., and soon the bottom fell out of the whale oil

        market, the price falling from $2.50 or more at its peak around

        l866 to well below a dollar.  And in 1993 we see Great Britain

        exporting both coal and oil.

             Here we should note that it was not the English government

        that developed coal or oil, because governments are not effective

        developers of new technology.  Rather, it was individual

        entrepreneurs who sensed the need, saw opportunity, used all

        kinds of available information and ideas, made lots of false

        starts which were very costly to many of those individuals but

        not to others, and eventually arrived at coal as a viable fuel --

        because there were enough independent individuals investigating

        the matter for at least some of them to arrive at sound ideas and

        methods.  And this happened in the context of a competitive

        enterprise system that worked to produce what was needed by the

        public.  And the entire process of impending shortage and new

        solution left us better off than if the shortage problem had

        never arisen.


                           THE ROLE OF ECONOMIC FREEDOM

             Here we must address another crucial element in the

        economics of resources and population -- the extent to which the

        political-social-economic system provides personal freedom from

        government coercion.  Skilled persons require an appropriate

        social and economic framework that provides incentives for

        working hard and taking risks, enabling their talents to flower

        and come to fruition.  The key elements of such a framework are

        economic liberty, respect for property, and fair and sensible

        rules of the market that are enforced equally for all.

             The world's problem is not too many people, but lack of

        political and economic freedom.  Powerful evidence comes from an

        extraordinary natural experiment that occurred starting in the

        1940s with three pairs of countries that have the same culture

        and history, and had much the same standard of living when they

        split apart after World War II -- East and West Germany, North

        and South Korea, Taiwan and China.  In each case the centrally

        planned communist country began with less population "pressure",

        as measured by density per square kilometer, than did the market-

        directed economy.  And the communist and non-communist countries

        also started with much the same birth rates.

             The market-directed economies have performed much better

        economically than the centrally-planned economies.  The economic-

        political system clearly was the dominant force in the results of

        the three comparisons.  This powerful explanation of economic

        development cuts the ground from under population growth as a

        likely explanation of the speed of nations' economic development.


                 THE ASTOUNDING SHIFT IN THE SCHOLARLY CONSENSUS

             So far we've been discussing the factual evidence.  But in

        1994 there is an important new element not present twenty years

        ago.  The scientific community of scholars who study population

        economics now agrees with almost all of what is written ahove.

        The statements made above do not represent a single lone voice,

        but rather the current scientific consensus.

             The conclusions offered earlier about agriculture and
        resources and demographic trends have always represented the
        consensus of economists in those fields.  And now the consensus
        of population economists also is now not far from what is written
        here.

             In 1986, the U. S.  National Research Council and the U. S.

        National Academy of Sciences published a book on population

        growth and economic development prepared by a prestigious

        scholarly group.  This "official" report reversed almost

        completely the frightening conclusions of the previous 1971 NAS

        report. "Population growth at most a minor factor..."  "The

        scarcity of exhaustible resources is at most a minor constraint

        on economic growth", it now says.  It found benefits of

        additional people as well as costs .

             A host of review articles by distinguished economic

        demographers in the past decade have confirmed that this

        "revisionist" view is indeed consistent with the scientific

        evidence, though not all the writers would go as far as I do in

        pointing out the positive long-run effects of population growth.

        The consensus is more toward a "neutral" judgment.  But this is a

        huge change from the earlier judgment that population growth is

        economically detrimental.

             By 1994, anyone who confidently asserts that population

        growth damages the economy must turn a blind eye to the scientif-

        ic evidence.


                              SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION

             In the short run, all resources are limited.  An example of

        such a finite resource is the amount of space allotted to me.

        The longer run, however, is a different story.  The standard of

        living has risen along with the size of the world's population

        since the beginning of recorded time.  There is no convincing

        economic reason why these trends toward a better life should not

        continue indefinitely.

             The key theoretical idea is this: The growth of population

        and of income create actual and expected shortages, and hence

        lead to price run-ups.  A price increase represents an

        opportunity that attracts profit-minded entrepreneurs to seek new

        ways to satisfy the shortages.  Some fail, at cost to themselves.

        A few succeed, and the final result is that we end up better off

        than if the original shortage problems had never arisen.  That

        is, we need our problems though this does not imply that we

        should purposely create additional problems for ourselves.

             I hope that you will now agree that the long-run outlook is

        for a more abundant material life rather than for increased

        scarcity, in the United States and in the world as a whole.  Of

        course such progress does not come about automatically.  And my

        message certainly is not one of complacency. In this I agree with

        the doomsayers - that our world needs the best efforts of all

        humanity to improve our lot.  I part company with them in that

        they expect us to come to a bad end despite the efforts we make,

        whereas I expect a continuation of humanity's history of

        successful efforts.  And I believe that their message is self-

        fulfilling, because if you expect your efforts to fail because of

        inexorable natural limits, then you are likely to feel resigned;

        and therefore to literally resign.  But if you recognize the

        possibility - in fact the probability - of success, you can tap

        large reservoirs of energy and enthusiasm.

             Adding more people causes problems, but people are also the

        means to solve these problems.  The main fuel to speed the

        world's progress is our stock of knowledge, and the brakes are a)

        our lack of imagination, and b) unsound social regulations of

        these activities.  The ultimate resource is people - especially

        skilled, spirited, and hopeful young people endowed with liberty

        - who will exert their wills and imaginations for their own

        benefit, and so inevitably they will benefit not only themselves

        but the rest of us as well.



        page 1 /article3 popenvi2/February 28, 1994


                                    REFERENCES

             Schultz, Theodore W., "The Declining Economic Importance of

        Land," Economic Journal, LXI, December, 1951, pp. 725-740.

             National Research Council, Committee on Population, and Working

        Group on Population Growth and Economic Development, Population

        Growth and Economic Development: Policy Questions (Washington, D.C.:

        National Academy Press, 1986)


        page 2 /article3 popenvi2/February 28, 1994



108 posted on 01/24/2012 8:50:17 AM PST by Brian Kopp DPM
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 106 | View Replies]

To: Mad Dawgg
Who is going to feed all those people standing shoulder to shoulder, what is going to prevent a disease from becoming an epidemic, who is going to provide them energy and products and services?

Just because you can physically fit 9 billion people in the State of Texas doesn't mean that they would live for long in such conditions.

So do you think illegal immigration is an economic boon to the USA because of the extra population it provides?

If not, why not?

9 billion people may well live comfortably and happily upon the Earth, with better utilization of resources - that may or may not be the point of “overpopulation” that leads to demographic contraction due to epidemic or starvation or warfare or whatever the ‘release valve’ of the overpopulation ends up being.

The Earth, with better technology, may well support 14 billion people in health and comfort.

And it looks like we had better start planing for such, because despite the idiotic ramblings of a not very bright religious devotee, the Earth's population is increasing and AT an increasing rate.

109 posted on 01/24/2012 8:54:44 AM PST by allmendream (Tea Party did not send the GOP to D.C. to negotiate the terms of our surrender to socialism.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 107 | View Replies]

To: allmendream
Global warming was a mainstream view until data demolished it.

Where is the data undercutting the widely reported and almost universally acknowledged EXPANDING human population?

Since you obviously are unwilling or unable to read the books and articles I've linked or posted on this thread, at least take a few minutes and watch the Demographic Winter documentary.

You can watch it for free on YouTube:

Demographic Winter - the decline of the human family (Full Movie)

110 posted on 01/24/2012 8:57:44 AM PST by Brian Kopp DPM
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 106 | View Replies]

To: Dr. Brian Kopp

I have read real souces, they and you both seem to agree that we are going to reach 9 billion long before the Earth’s population contracts, if it contracts.

I understand math, and realize that a slight decline in the birth rate of 7 billion people still adds population to the Earth faster than 6 billion people at a slightly higher birth rate.

Even you acknowledge the EXPANDING human population.

Do you now want to retract your statment?

Did you not read the books and articles you linked - because you just this morning opined that the “EXPANDING human population” I made reference to, the one that made you think I didn’t read your inane argument, was going to EXPAND to possibly 9 billion.

So we both seem in agreement that the human population of the Earth is increasing, and likely to keep increasing up to 9 billion or more.

Unless you are so incapble of a cogent argument that you are now going to retract your opinion that we have an expanding human population.

Still haven’t answerd a rather simple question about illegal immigration.

Do you think the excess population that illegal immigration provides to these United States is an economic boon or not?

Don’t be a coward and just cut and paste a bunch of irrelevant crap again - answer the question.

This should be amusing!!!! ;)


111 posted on 01/24/2012 9:05:22 AM PST by allmendream (Tea Party did not send the GOP to D.C. to negotiate the terms of our surrender to socialism.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 110 | View Replies]

To: allmendream
Do you think the excess population that illegal immigration provides to these United States is an economic boon or not?

Illegal immigrants are helping to prop up the Ponzi scheme of our social welfare programs. Since Americans are not reproducing in adequate numbers to prop it up, both parties understand that to close the border will bring insolvency to Social Security and Medicare that much faster.

That's the reason neither party is interested in closing the border, and both parties want to naturalize illegal immigrants - to get them paying into the coffers and prop up the failing system.

Short term illegal immigration is obviously an economic burden.

Long term, they can and do become contributing members (i.e., paying Social Security taxes, just like all immigrants and descendants of immigrants in our history) of society, and help forestall the economic collapse that will come as a result of decreasing fertility rates.

112 posted on 01/24/2012 9:15:37 AM PST by Brian Kopp DPM
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 111 | View Replies]

To: allmendream
So we both seem in agreement that the human population of the Earth is increasing, and likely to keep increasing up to 9 billion or more.

And that is simply a result of the increasing life expectancy -- which has peaked) counterbalancing the rapidly declining fertility rate (which has not bottomed out, and is accelerating in Third World countries.

At some point, the scales are going to tip, and as those who benefited from the increased life expectancy die off, and global fertility rates continue to decline, global population will peak then rapidly contract.

It might peak at 8 or 9 billion, maybe less, but once it does, the aging population will die off rapidly and global population will decline.

Which part of this do you not understand?

113 posted on 01/24/2012 9:30:12 AM PST by Brian Kopp DPM
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 111 | View Replies]

To: allmendream
I understand math, and realize that a slight decline in the birth rate of 7 billion people still adds population to the Earth faster than 6 billion people at a slightly higher birth rate.

Not after fertility rates drop below 2.1, and the elderly who benefited from increased life expectancy start dying off.

There will be no further increases in life expectancy, and the decreases in fertility rates are well documented and accelerating.

Which part of this simple equation do you not grasp?

114 posted on 01/24/2012 9:46:19 AM PST by Brian Kopp DPM
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 111 | View Replies]

To: Dr. Brian Kopp
The part I am “not getting” is where we both agree that human population is increasing and may well reach 9 billion in our lifetime - but somehow your propose I am not understanding your inane ramblings when I speak of an EXPANDING human population - something you I and everyone else seems to agree is the reality of the situation.

Another part I am “not getting” is where illegal immigration is an economic boon to the USA - they consume far more in socialized benefits than they contribute to in terms of taxes, reduce the price of labor, and increase the cost of insurance education and health care.

Another thing I am “not getting” is how a slight decline in birth rates for 7 billion people is a problem when it is going to get us to 8 billion people a lot faster than we went from 6 to 7 billion.

You are absolutely delusional if you think human population is decreasing or that the greatest threat to humanity is our lack of fecundity. 7 billion people and rapidly rising to 8 billion at an ever increasing rate (despite a slight dip in birth rates), and you think human fecundity is a problem IN THE OTHER DIRECTION?

Good luck pounding the underpopulation drum in a world with 8 billion people rapidly on the way to 9 billion!

Delusional barely even covers such inanity!

115 posted on 01/24/2012 9:53:12 AM PST by allmendream (Tea Party did not send the GOP to D.C. to negotiate the terms of our surrender to socialism.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 113 | View Replies]

To: Dr. Brian Kopp; allmendream

allmendrean’s posts usually have a subtle creepiness to them. I wouldn’t spend too much time arguing with him.


116 posted on 01/24/2012 9:56:00 AM PST by Tramonto (Draft Palin)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 114 | View Replies]

To: allmendream
"Just because you can physically fit 9 billion people in the State of Texas doesn't mean that they would live for long in such conditions."

Actually you can physically fit 9 Billion people in the State of Rhode Island and still have a bit of room leftover. (BTW the answer to the question is 0 States.)

Further I never advocated allowing any illegal in here I am for a Wall on all borders manned 24/7 by tough Hombres like the Marines with orders to shoot to kill anyone trying to get in illegally!

I just point out that the Point is that the Overpopulation Myth is just that MYTH! If we take ALL the people of the world and set them up in the USA spreading them out so they could live comfortably then you would have the rest of the Earth to farm and use for Resources. Point is the EARTH is HUGE in comparison to the Human Population. And the only reason their are people going hungry right now is that Governments are so inefficient at handling resources that they waste more than they use to produce anything.

It is the very reason why Socialism doesn't work. You want everyone fed and happy them give them property rights and toss these Socialist Governments (Starting with the Obamanation) aside and you will see Prosperity Worldwide.

117 posted on 01/24/2012 9:57:08 AM PST by Mad Dawgg (If you're going to deny my 1st Amendment rights then I must proceed to the 2nd one...)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 109 | View Replies]

To: Tramonto
Logic and reality are creepy concepts to some.

But yes, arguing with fanatics who think underpopulation is a problem in a world with 7 billion people rapidly rising to 8 billion isn't the best use of time.

Amusing, but not likely to garner positive results.

So back to your regularly scheduled delusional pro-illegal immigration, anti-birthcontrol religious dogma.

118 posted on 01/24/2012 9:59:21 AM PST by allmendream (Tea Party did not send the GOP to D.C. to negotiate the terms of our surrender to socialism.)
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 116 | View Replies]

To: allmendream
You are confusing population momentum with indefinite population growth. At present, 42% of the world's population lives in countries with sub-replacement fertility rates, but by 2050, projections are that the vast majority of the world's population, including third world nations, will be at sub-replacement fertility.

We all dislike WikiPedia, but their explanation might assist you in coming to terms with this reality (I bolded the important part to assist you):

Sub-replacement fertility do not immediately translate into a population decline because of population momentum: recently high fertility rates produce a disproportionately young population, and younger populations have higher birth rates. This is why some nations with sub-replacement fertility still have a growing population, because a relatively large fraction of their population are still of child-bearing age. But if the fertility trend is sustained (and not compensated by immigration), it results in population ageing and population decline. This is forecast for most of the countries of Europe and East Asia.

Current estimates expect the world's total fertility rate to fall below replacement levels by 2050,[18] although population momentum will continue to increase global population for several generations beyond that. The promise of eventual population decline helps reduce concerns of overpopulation, but many[who?] believe the Earth's carrying capacity has already been exceeded and that even a stable population would not be sustainable.

Some believe that not only this (apparent) economic depression we have entered, but the 'Great Depression' of the 1930's (and beyond?) may be, and may have been, the result of a decline in birthrates overall. Clarence L. Barber, an economist at the University of Manitoba, pointed out how demand for housing in the US, for example, began to decline in 1926, due to a decline in 'household formation' (marriage), due, he believed, to the effects of World War I upon society. In early 1929, US housing demand declined precipitously. And, of course, the stock market crash followed in October of that same year. [19]

Even though the overall world population continues to "grow", it is more at the 'back end' than the 'front end' that this is occurring. That is, more people are kept alive than in the past due to improved nutrition, more refrigeration and better sanitation worldwide, as well as health care advances, from vaccines to antibiotics, and many other advances in medications and in different improvements in health care. Certainly, in advanced nations, few groups would be considered to be "breeding like rabbits". The 'baby boom' (1946-1964) in the US, was likely, if Barber's hunches are correct, more of a return to birthrates closer to historical norms, like those of the first decade of the 20th century (but the 'baby boom' of 1946-1964 were still lower than the 1900-1910 period), with birth dearths both before and since making the so-called "baby boom" appear so big. The pig in the snake wasn't so big. It is more that the periods before and after it were so skinny!

Sub-replacement fertility can also change social relations in a society. Fewer children, combined with lower infant mortality has made the death of children a far greater tragedy in the modern world than it was just fifty years ago. Having many families with only one or two children also reduces greatly the number of siblings, aunts and uncles, making this 'demographic winter' much of the world is in not only 'colder', but also much lonelier. This may be the reason that Europeans, overall, appear more reluctant to send their sons to war, including Russians to Afghanistan and Chechnya, than Americans have been (even though US fertility rates are, in some comparisons, only marginally higher).

Population aging poses an economic cost on societies, as the number of elderly retirees rises in relation to the number of young workers. This has been raised as a political issue in France, Germany, and the United States, where many people have advocated policy changes to encourage higher fertility and immigration rates. In France, payments to couples who have children have increased birthrates.[20]


119 posted on 01/24/2012 10:05:05 AM PST by Brian Kopp DPM
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 115 | View Replies]

To: allmendream
You are absolutely delusional if you think human population is decreasing or that the greatest threat to humanity is our lack of fecundity. 7 billion people and rapidly rising to 8 billion at an ever increasing rate (despite a slight dip in birth rates), and you think human fecundity is a problem IN THE OTHER DIRECTION?

In the developed world, all other things being equal, you must have an ongoing fertility rate of 2.1 simply to maintain a population. In the third world, all other things being equal, you must have an ongoing fertility rate of 2.33 simply to maintain a population.

The global fertilty rate at present is 2.56 according to the CIA. It is expected to drop below 2.1 by 2050, probably sooner. At that point, the population momentum (see my last post) ceases, and population contraction starts, when the increased longevity has fully played out (it already has.)

120 posted on 01/24/2012 10:12:45 AM PST by Brian Kopp DPM
[ Post Reply | Private Reply | To 115 | View Replies]


Navigation: use the links below to view more comments.
first previous 1-20 ... 81-100101-120121-140 ... 161-171 next last

Disclaimer: Opinions posted on Free Republic are those of the individual posters and do not necessarily represent the opinion of Free Republic or its management. All materials posted herein are protected by copyright law and the exemption for fair use of copyrighted works.

Free Republic
Browse · Search
Bloggers & Personal
Topics · Post Article

FreeRepublic, LLC, PO BOX 9771, FRESNO, CA 93794
FreeRepublic.com is powered by software copyright 2000-2008 John Robinson